Efforts to reform competition law proceed at different levels of generality. Some bills would tackle antitrust writ large. Others are more focused, applying special rules to a handful of Big Tech companies. The Open App Markets Act (OAMA) is narrower still, targeting one segment of the digital economy—mobile software application (app) stores—with sectoral regulation.
While limited in scope, the legislation would reshape key technology markets. Last year, the two largest app stores—Apple's App Store and Google Play—generated combined sales of $133 billion, which reportedly contributed a fifth of the operating profits at Apple and at Google parent Alphabet. The OAMA (S. 2710, H.R. 5017, and H.R. 7030) would require these firms to make major changes to their business practices in the name of protecting app developers and consumers from alleged abuses of monopoly power.
This Sidebar provides an overview of S. 2710, a version of the OAMA which the Senate Judiciary Committee advanced with amendments in February 2022.
Competition Issues in the App Industry
App stores are considered critical nodes in the digital economy, enabling software developers to distribute their apps to mobile-device users. In turn, those apps allow consumers to perform a sweeping array of tasks, ranging from messaging to gaming to ordering food.
The app-store market is dominated by Apple and Google, which also control the leading mobile operating systems (iOS and Android). Both the app-store market and the market for mobile operating systems contain high entry barriers and exhibit strong network effects, potentially giving Apple and Google significant power to shape the app industry.
Global competition authorities have investigated several ways in which the firms have allegedly abused that power. The practices motivating the OAMA's proponents include:
The Legislation
The OAMA would prohibit many of the practices described above. The bill would impose the following prohibitions and requirements on firms that own or control app stores with more than 50 million U.S. users.
These requirements and prohibitions would not be absolute. S. 2710 would offer covered companies several affirmative defenses. In particular, a covered company would not be in violation of any of the provisions discussed above for an action that is:
To prevail under these defenses, a covered company would need to show by a preponderance of the evidence that its action was non-pretextual, applied consistently to all apps, and "narrowly tailored and could not be achieved through a less discriminatory and technically possible means."
S. 2710 would grant enforcement authority to the Federal Trade Commission and state attorneys general. The bill would also provide a private right of action for treble damages to injured app developers, with the exception of app developers owned or controlled by a foreign state.
Analysis
There are several strategies for addressing concerns about excessive market power. First there is antitrust, a common law system of adjudication that requires courts to apply broad principles—no unreasonable restraints of trade, monopolization, or unfair methods of competition—to specific fact patterns. This approach is already being deployed to combat allegedly anticompetitive conduct in the app economy. Developers, consumers, and state attorneys general have brought antitrust lawsuits against Apple and Google that are currently working their way through the courts.
Ex ante regulation represents a second approach to market power. While antitrust lawsuits require courts to determine after the fact whether challenged conduct violates certain general standards, regulation identifies specific practices as lawful or unlawful before a firm engages in them.
There are also a variety of approaches that lie somewhere between antitrust and regulation. One scholar has employed the term administration to describe systems that rely primarily on informal solutions and negotiated agreements between regulated parties and their regulators. The Hart-Scott-Rodino merger-review regime—in which regulators and merging parties can agree to bespoke remedies that ameliorate competition concerns—is one example. Another commentator has identified an agency-oversight model in which a specialist regulator is tasked with implementing general standards and exercising ongoing supervision over regulated entities.
Each modality has potential costs and benefits for different stakeholders. Antitrust is flexible, but can be slow and may not produce guidance that can be generalized for use by non-parties. Policymakers also may not like prevailing antitrust doctrine at any given point in time. For its part, regulation may be faster and provide greater certainty than antitrust lawsuits, but can err by being over-inclusive. Finally, intermediate approaches that combine ongoing agency oversight with flexible legal standards can work quickly and potentially avoid the error costs of regulation, but may create institutions that are vulnerable to regulatory capture.
This rough taxonomy offers a framework for evaluating the OAMA and its alternatives. The bill embraces the regulatory approach to promoting competition in app markets, prohibiting covered companies from engaging in specified categories of conduct. Accordingly, the legislation may have efficiency advantages over antitrust litigation, which can be costly and time-consuming. The OAMA would also hedge against the possibility that plaintiffs will not prevail in such litigation. (A game developer is currently appealing a lower-court decision rejecting its federal antitrust claims against Apple.)
At the same time, regulation arguably entails higher potential error costs than antitrust. While a court adjudicating an antitrust dispute can delve deeply into a detailed factual record, bright-line rules apply broadly and may condemn some procompetitive conduct. For example, Apple has argued that rules requiring it to allow app sideloading and the use of alternative IAP processors will threaten the security of iOS devices. Likewise, some commentators have argued that a categorical prohibition of sherlocking would be on net anticompetitive. (When Apple or Google integrates a feature into their operating systems that was previously supplied by third parties for a fee, consumers may benefit even if third-party developers suffer.)
More generally, supporters of Apple and Google have argued that existing app-store revenue models produce several benefits that the OAMA would disrupt. In particular, the current commission-based model may subsidize upstart developers by forcing popular apps to bear most of the costs of maintaining the relevant platforms. Observers have also argued that the revenue Apple and Google derive from their app ecosystems may allow the firms to lower prices elsewhere. Google, for instance, has argued that pre-installation of its search engine allows it to monetize Android, which it otherwise might not license to device manufacturers for free. One scholar has similarly suggested that Apple may charge less for its devices because of the revenue it earns from apps and IAPs.
While antitrust and regulation have recognized costs and benefits, intermediate approaches to digital competition have received less attention in the United States. The United Kingdom (U.K.), however, is developing one such strategy. The U.K.'s Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) has established a Digital Markets Unit (DMU) to oversee firms with "strategic market status." While Parliament has yet to adopt legislation empowering the new unit, the CMA's proposal envisions a regime in which the DMU would develop firm-specific codes of conduct to achieve the general objectives of "fair trading," "open choices," and "trust and transparency."
Other countries have gone in a different direction. South Korea recently adopted rules prohibiting dominant app stores from forcing developers to use their in-app purchase processors. The European Union is also considering comprehensive legislation that would impose ex ante regulations on digital "gatekeepers," with several of the rules mirroring provisions in the OAMA. Congress thus has several possible models to draw from in developing its approach to competition issues in app markets.