← Browse

The Role of Patents and Regulatory Exclusivities in Drug Pricing

The Role of Patents and Regulatory Exclusivities in Drug Pricing
Updated January 30, 2024 (R46679)
Jump to Main Text of Report

Contents

Summary

Intellectual property (IP) rights play an important role in the development and pricing of prescription drugs and biologics. To encourage innovation, IP law grants inventors exclusive rights in a particular invention or product, potentially enabling them to charge higher-than-competitive prices. IP rights are typically justified as necessary to allow pharmaceutical manufacturers the ability to recoup substantial costs in research and development, including clinical trials and other tests necessary to obtain regulatory approval from the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA). However, IP rights have been criticized as contributing to high prices for pharmaceutical products in the United States by operating to deter or delay competition from generic drug and biosimilar manufacturers.

Two main types of IP rights may protect pharmaceutical products: patents and regulatory exclusivities. Patents, which are available for a wide range of technologies beyond pharmaceuticals, are granted by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). Patents may claim chemical compounds in the pharmaceutical product, a method of using the product, a method of making or administering the product, or a variety of other patentable inventions relating to a drug or biologic. The holder of a valid patent generally has the exclusive right to make, use, sell, and import the invention for a term lasting approximately 20 years. Pharmaceutical patent disputes are subject to certain specialized procedures under the Hatch-Waxman Act and the Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act (BPCIA), which can affect when generic and biosimilar manufacturers can market their follow-on products.

In addition to patent protection, certain pharmaceuticals, such as innovative products or those that serve particular needs, may qualify for periods of regulatory exclusivity when they are approved or licensed by FDA. Pharmaceutical products may only be sold in the United States after FDA has determined they are safe and effective, based on submitted data, and has approved or licensed them. FDA generally may not accept and/or approve a generic drug or biosimilar if the pharmaceutical product being used as a reference to show the follow-on product is safe and effective is covered by an unexpired regulatory exclusivity. Regulatory exclusivities vary in length from six months to 12 years, depending on the basis for the exclusivity.

Because the exclusivity that IP rights provide may enable the rights holder (e.g., a brand-name drug manufacturer) to charge higher-than-competitive prices for a period of time, rights holders may have an incentive to lengthen that time period as much as possible. Some commentators allege that certain brand-name drug manufacturers have engaged in patenting practices that unduly extend the period of exclusivity. Critics argue that these patenting practices are used to keep drug prices high, without significant benefits for consumers or innovation. Such patenting practices include so-called (1) patent "evergreening," (2) "product hopping," (3) "patent thickets," and (4) "pay-for-delay" settlements. Patent "evergreening" is the alleged practice of filing for new patents on secondary features of a pharmaceutical as earlier patents expire, thereby extending effective patent exclusivity past the original 20-year term. "Product hopping" is the alleged practice of a brand manufacturer attempting to switch the market to a new, similar product covered by later-expiring patents before IP rights on an existing product expire. "Patent thickets" refer to portfolios of numerous, overlapping patents on the same pharmaceutical, which allegedly deter competition due to the risk of infringement and the high cost of patent litigation. "Pay-for-delay" or "reverse payment" settlements resolve patent litigation through payments or other compensation from a brand to a generic or biosimilar manufacturer to delay generic market entry. In some cases, these settlements may be anticompetitive because they allow the brand to continue to charge high prices without risking invalidation of its patent.

Drug manufacturers counter that their patenting practices protect new and useful inventions as Congress intended when it created the patent system. In their view, the terms for these practices are unfairly pejorative, or, at most, describe outlier behavior by a few companies. Defenders of these patenting practices reject their characterization as anticompetitive and emphasize that strong patent rights encourage innovation and life-saving research and development efforts.


The prices consumers pay for prescription drugs has long been of significant congressional interest. In recent Congresses, several House and Senate committees held hearings on drug pricing issues,1 and Members introduced dozens of bills to address the perceived high costs of prescription drugs and other pharmaceutical products.2 Growth in U.S. expenditures on prescription drugs—which for decades rose at double-digit rates annually—has moderated in recent years and is projected to continue to grow by about 5.5% per year (roughly in line with increases in general health care spending).3 Despite recent fluctuations, consumers in the United States generally pay significantly higher prices for prescription drugs as compared to other developed countries.4

Many factors contribute to the prices consumers pay for drugs and biologics, including demand, manufacturing costs, research and development (R&D) costs, the terms of private health insurance, and the involvement of a government insurance program such as Medicaid or Medicare.5 Pharmaceutical products are often protected by intellectual property (IP) rights,6 and some studies suggest that IP rights are among the most important factors driving high drug prices.7 For example, the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) has found that increased competition from generic drug manufacturers is associated with much lower prices for pharmaceuticals.8

Given that IP rights can deter or delay the market entry of generic drug or biosimilar competition, and thus may allow the rights holder to charge higher-than-competitive prices, some see changing IP rights as a potential way to lower prices for pharmaceutical products.9 Other stakeholders are wary of undermining IP rights, which play an important role in facilitating development of new pharmaceutical products.10 A key focus of this debate, then, is whether existing IP law properly balances the need for innovation with the costs that IP rights may impose on consumers and the public.11 Understanding the interplay between several complex legal regimes is necessary to understand this debate.

The scope and enforcement of IP rights in pharmaceutical products depends upon several underlying legal and regulatory regimes, including FDA law, patent law, and antitrust law. In addition to patent protection, certain pharmaceuticals, such as innovative products or those that serve particular needs, may qualify for periods of regulatory exclusivity when they are approved or licensed by FDA.12 FDA regulates pharmaceutical products differently if they derive from biological, as opposed to chemical, sources. In particular, under the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act (FD&C Act), FDA must approve nonbiological "drugs" before they can be marketed or sold,13 whereas "biologics"14 must be licensed by FDA under the Public Health Service Act (PHSA).15

This regulatory distinction has patent law consequences because patents on pharmaceutical drugs or biologics are subject to different specialized patent dispute resolution procedures, which can affect another manufacturer's ability to bring a generic drug or biosimilar version of an existing product to market. Provisions of the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984 (the Hatch-Waxman Act)16 govern FDA approval and patent disputes for generic drugs, whereas the Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act of 2009 (BPCIA)17 governs FDA licensure and patent disputes for biosimilars.

Given these complexities, a fair amount of legal background is necessary to understand how drug manufacturers obtain and enforce IP rights in pharmaceuticals and how IP rights may impact drug prices. This report provides this background, proceeding in five parts. First, it provides an overview of the economic rationale for intellectual property in the pharmaceutical context and IP law's fundamental policy tradeoff between providing incentives for innovation without unduly increasing prices for consumers. Second, the report overviews FDA requirements for obtaining approval to market a drug or biological product, the abbreviated pathways for generic drug approval under the Hatch-Waxman Act and biosimilar licensure under the BPCIA, and different regulatory exclusivities that FDA grants to certain approved pharmaceutical products.18 Third, it reviews patent law, including the requirements for obtaining a patent, the rights granted to patent holders, and various limitations on those rights.19 Fourth, the report describes and compares the different specialized patent dispute procedures for generic drugs and biosimilars under the Hatch-Waxman Act and the BPCIA, respectively.20 Finally, it overviews antitrust law and describes its application to several patenting practices used by pharmaceutical companies to enforce their IP rights, and overviews the debates between various stakeholders over such practices.21

IP Rights in Pharmaceuticals: Incentives for Innovation Versus Cost and Access

In general, IP law comprises a set of exclusive rights that prevent others from making, copying, or using certain intangible creations of the human mind.22 Federal law provides legal protection for several different varieties of IP.23 Each form of IP covers a different type of intellectual creation, has a different procedure for obtaining rights, and grants the IP owner legal rights that vary in scope and duration.24

New pharmaceutical products generally benefit from two primary forms25 of IP protection: patent rights and regulatory exclusivities.26 These two sets of exclusive rights are distinct, yet often confused. In overlapping ways, both patent rights and regulatory exclusivities can operate to prevent or delay the market entry of a generic drug or biosimilar version of a brand-name drug or biologic.

Patents, which are available to many technologies beyond pharmaceuticals,27 are granted by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) for inventions that are new, useful, nonobvious, and directed at patentable subject matter.28 The holder of a valid patent generally has the exclusive right to make, use, sell, or import a patented invention within the United States for a period beginning when the PTO issues the patent and ending twenty years after the filing date of the patent application.29

Regulatory exclusivities are granted to qualifying pharmaceutical products upon being approved or licensed for marketing by FDA.30 Only certain pharmaceutical products, such as innovative products (e.g., a new active ingredient or new indication for an existing drug) or those that serve a specific need (e.g., treating rare diseases), receive such exclusivities.31 Regulatory exclusivities generally prevent FDA from accepting or approving an application for a follow-on product (i.e., a generic or biosimilar version) of a previously approved pharmaceutical that relies on safety and efficacy data submitted by the original manufacturer for a period of time.32 Depending on the type of pharmaceutical product and other factors, regulatory exclusivities may last anywhere from six months to twelve years.33

Although each of these forms of IP is legally distinct, they broadly share a common motivation: encouraging innovation.34 Patents are typically justified by a utilitarian rationale that exclusive rights are necessary to provide incentives to produce new creative works and technological inventions.35 This rationale maintains that absent legal protections, competitors could freely copy such creations, denying the original creators the ability to recoup their investments in time and effort, thereby reducing the incentive to create in the first place.36 IP incentives are said to be particularly necessary for products, such as pharmaceuticals, that are costly to develop but easily copied once marketed.37 In the words of the Supreme Court, IP rights are premised on an "economic philosophy" that the "encouragement of individual effort by personal gain is the best way to advance public welfare through the talents of authors and inventors."38 From this perspective, the fundamental aim of IP law is to find the optimal balance between providing incentives for innovation and the costs that IP rights impose on the public.39 Regulatory exclusivities, too, ideally seek to balance encouraging innovation and encouraging competition.40

By design, IP rights may lead to increased prices for IP-protected goods or services. IP rights are often said to grant a temporary "monopoly" to the rights holder.41 The existence of a patent on a particular manufacturing process, for example, generally means that only the patent holder (and persons licensed by the patent holder) can use that patented process until the patent expires.42 In some circumstances, this legal exclusivity may allow the patent holder (or her licensees) to charge higher-than-competitive prices for goods made with the patented process, as a monopolist would, because the patent effectively shields the patent holder from competition.43

As a result, a patent holder, such as a drug manufacturer, may have an incentive to prolong the period of exclusivity, such as by filing for additional patents to cover a product.44 In the pharmaceutical context, critics argue that some brand-name drug and biological product manufacturers (the brands) use patenting strategies to "game[] the patent system" to maximize profits and forestall competition from generic drug or biosimilar manufacturers (the generics).45 Others contend that these practices are a legitimate use of the patent system and are necessary to incentivize the billions of dollars in R&D that lead to new, life-saving drugs.46 As these pharmaceutical patenting practices may affect drug prices, they have attracted congressional interest. Several legislative proposals seek to curtail these patenting practices by reducing their effectiveness or outlawing them entirely.47 Proponents see such legislation as a potential way to lower pharmaceutical prices.48 Later sections of this report discuss four such alleged patenting practices: "evergreening," "product hopping," "patent thickets," and "pay-for-delay" settlements.49

FDA Approval and Licensure of Pharmaceutical Products

The FD&C Act generally promotes public health by protecting consumers from pharmaceuticals that are adulterated, misbranded, unsafe, or ineffective.50 To this end, new drugs and biologics cannot be marketed in the United States without FDA approval.51 FDA law also balances encouraging advancements in medicine through innovation against the benefits of competition, similar to patent law.52 To that end, federal law provides certain regulatory exclusivities—generally awarded upon approval—for pharmaceutical products that meet the requisite criteria.53

FDA determines which drugs and biologics may be marketed in the United States through similar but distinct approval processes.54 This section first overviews the approval processes for new and generic drugs, and then discusses the processes for new and follow-on biologics. It also describes the exclusivities Congress has created to encourage research and development of new pharmaceutical products as well as competition from follow-on products.

New and Generic Drug Approval

Drugs are articles—generally chemical compounds—"intended for use in the diagnosis, cure, mitigation, treatment, or prevention of disease" or "intended to affect the structure or any function of the body."55 New drugs, as the term is used in the FD&C Act, are those drugs that scientific experts do not generally recognize as safe and effective for their intended use.56 A new drug may contain an active ingredient that FDA has not previously approved, or may contain a previously approved active ingredient with the drug modified in one or more other aspects from the approved drug, such as the indication, patient population, formulation, strength, dosage form, or route of administration. All new drugs require FDA approval before they are marketed in the United States.57

New Drug Approval

New drugs are approved through the new drug application (NDA) process. To obtain approval for a new drug, a sponsor must conduct "costly and time-consuming studies,"58 including clinical trials, demonstrating the drug's safety59 and effectiveness60 for humans.61 Clinical trials, conducted after the company has completed basic research and nonclinical testing, assess the safety, efficacy, and effectiveness of the drug in volunteer human subjects under carefully controlled conditions.62 When the company is ready to begin clinical trials, it submits an investigational new drug (IND) application to FDA.63 The IND application provides FDA with information about the drug as well as a proposed clinical study design that has been reviewed and approved by an Institutional Review Board (IRB).64 Unless FDA objects within 30 days of receiving the IND application, clinical investigations may proceed.65

Clinical testing occurs in three phases.66 Phase I clinical trials generally test the drug in a small number of subjects and focus on evaluating the drug's safety.67 During Phase I clinical trials, the sponsor evaluates how the drug is processed (metabolized and excreted) in the body, determines the highest tolerable dose and optimal dose of the drug, and identifies any acute adverse side effects of the drug.68 Phase II and Phase III clinical trials evaluate the drug's efficacy in addition to continuing to evaluate safety.69 These trials generally use a larger group of test subjects who have the characteristic, condition, or disease the drug treats.70 Phase II studies generally are still well-controlled and "usually involv[e] no more than several hundred subjects," whereas Phase III studies may include expanded controlled and uncontrolled trials and "usually include from several hundred to several thousand subjects."71

Once clinical trials are complete, the sponsor may submit the results to FDA's Center for Drug Evaluation and Research (CDER) in an NDA.72 The NDA also includes information about the drug, proposed labeling, and planned manufacturing process.73

FDA reviews the NDA to determine whether there is "substantial evidence" that the drug is safe and effective for the proposed use, including whether the benefits of the drug outweigh the risks.74 Section 505(d) of the FD&C Act defines substantial evidence to mean "adequate and well-controlled investigations" based on which qualified scientific experts could "fairly and responsibly" conclude that the product has the purported effect.75 FDA assesses both the quality and quantity of the data provided when determining whether a product meets this standard.76 The agency also reviews the proposed labeling and the manufacturing controls.77

FDA sends a letter to the drug sponsor with the agency's determination.78 If the NDA meets the requirements for approval, FDA sends an approval letter or, if patent rights or exclusivities bar immediate approval, a tentative approval letter.79 FDA may impose conditions on its approval of an NDA, such as requiring the company to conduct additional post-market clinical studies, referred to as Phase IV clinical trials.80 If the NDA does not meet the requirements for approval, FDA sends a complete response letter explaining the deficiencies FDA identified in the NDA and how they might be remedied.81

Generic Drug Approval

Before the Hatch-Waxman Act was enacted in 1984, every new drug submitted to FDA for preapproval required a complete application under Section 505(b) supported by clinical trial data demonstrating safety and effectiveness.82 To encourage generic drug entry, the Hatch-Waxman Act established a pathway for abbreviated new drug applications (ANDAs),83 which allows generic manufacturers to rely on FDA's prior approval of another drug with the same active ingredient—the reference listed drug (RLD)—to establish that the generic drug is safe and effective.84 The ANDA pathway allows generic manufacturers to avoid the long, expensive process of conducting their own clinical trials.85 The generic manufacturer need only conduct studies with its generic product and samples of the RLD to demonstrate that the generic drug is pharmaceutically equivalent86 and bioequivalent87 to the RLD.88 The ANDA also includes the generic manufacturer's proposed labeling, which must be identical to the RLD's labeling except for manufacturing information and any FDA-approved changes.89 ANDA filers submit information on pharmaceutical equivalence and bioequivalence studies, proposed labeling, and any patent certifications90 to FDA to obtain approval.91

Biological Product and Biosimilar Licensure

A biological product is derived from biological material, such as a virus, toxin, blood component, or protein, and used for "the prevention, treatment, or cure of a disease or condition of human beings."92 Biological products "are generally large, complex molecules" that "may be produced through biotechnology in a living system, such as a microorganism, plant cell, or animal cell."93 "Inherent variations" between different batches of the same biological product are "normal and expected."94 According to FDA, the complexity and variability of biological products "can present challenges in characterizing and manufacturing these products that often do not exist in the development of small molecule drugs."95 FDA's process for approving biological products and generic versions of previously approved products aims to account for these challenges.

Biological Products

To be marketed in the United States, a biological product must be (1) covered by a valid biologics license and (2) marked with the product's proper name; the manufacturer's name, address, and applicable license number; and the product's expiration date.96 A biological product manufacturer may obtain a biologics license by submitting a biologics license application (BLA) to FDA's Center for Biologics Evaluation and Research (CBER) or CDER for approval.97 The BLA must include, among other things, data from nonclinical and clinical studies, information about the manufacturing methods and locations, proposed labels and containers to be used, and (if applicable) a proposed Medication Guide.98 FDA must also be able to examine the product and determine that it "complies with the standards established" in the BLA and other requirements, including good manufacturing practices.99

To approve a BLA, FDA must determine that the biological product is "safe, pure, and potent" and that the production and distribution process "meets standards designed to assure that the biological product continues to be safe, pure, and potent."100 As with drug approvals, FDA either issues the license or issues a complete response letter detailing the reasons for denying the license.101 After approval, BLA holders must notify FDA of any changes to "the product, production process, quality controls, equipment, facilities, responsible personnel, or labeling."102

Biosimilar or Interchangeable Products

As with the Hatch-Waxman Act, Congress created an abbreviated approval process for biological products through BPCIA. Under the abbreviated process, a company can obtain a license to market a biological product if it can demonstrate that the product is biosimilar to, or interchangeable with, an approved biological product, referred to as the "reference product."103

Along with its BLA for a biosimilar, the manufacturer must submit data demonstrating that its product is "highly similar to the reference product notwithstanding minor differences in clinically inactive components" with no "clinically meaningful differences" between the two products "in terms of the safety, purity, and potency of the product."104 "[T]he condition or conditions of use prescribed, recommended, or suggested in the labeling" must have been approved for the reference product.105 The biosimilar product must use "the same mechanism or mechanisms of action" to treat any applicable conditions, and have the same route of administration, dosage form, and strength as the reference product.106 Finally, the biosimilar product license application must demonstrate that the production and distribution facilities meet "standards designed to assure that the biological product continues to be safe, pure, and potent."107

Along with a BLA for an interchangeable product, the manufacturer must submit data demonstrating that the product is biosimilar to the reference product and "can be expected to produce the same clinical result as the reference product in any given patient."108 Additionally, for a biological product administered to an individual more than once, the manufacturer must also show that the product does not create a greater "risk in terms of safety or diminished efficacy" from alternating or switching between the biosimilar product and reference product than if the reference product was used alone.109 Interchangeable products "may be substituted for the reference product without the intervention of the health care provider who prescribed the reference product."110

Regulatory Exclusivities

To balance increasing competition—which the abbreviated approval pathways aim to facilitate—with the countervailing interest in encouraging innovation, federal law establishes periods of regulatory exclusivity that limit FDA's ability to approve generic drugs and biosimilars under certain circumstances.111 These regulatory exclusivities aim to encourage companies to incur the expense of generating clinical data and other information needed to support an NDA or BLA for new drugs or biological products.112 They also encourage follow-on product manufacturers to submit abbreviated applications as soon as permissible.113

There are two general categories of regulatory exclusivity: (1) data exclusivity, which precludes other applicants from relying on FDA's safety and effectiveness findings for the reference product (based on the NDA or BLA holder's data) to demonstrate a follow-on product's safety and effectiveness; and (2) marketing exclusivity, which precludes FDA from approving any other application for the same pharmaceutical product and use, regardless of whether the applicant has generated its own safety and effectiveness data.114 During a period of data exclusivity, a company could submit an NDA or BLA for the same pharmaceutical product and use if it conducted its own clinical trials.115 Functionally, data exclusivity and marketing exclusivity may generate the same result due to the investment required to generate the necessary data.

New Drugs or Biological Products

Federal law provides regulatory exclusivities for new drug and biological products that differ based on such factors as how innovative the product is or the nature of the treatment population. For new drugs, an NDA filer who obtains approval for a drug that contains a new chemical entity (i.e., a new active ingredient) for which no other drug has been approved is eligible for five years of data exclusivity running from the time of NDA approval.116 During that period, no ANDA or 505(b)(2) NDA (i.e., applications that, by definition, would reference the NDA data) containing the same active ingredient as the RLD may be submitted to FDA.117 One exception is that after four years, FDA may accept for review an ANDA or 505(b)(2) application for the same active ingredient if the application contains a paragraph IV certification that a patent listed in the "Orange Book"—an FDA publication that catalogs the patents associated with each approved drug118—for the RLD is either invalid or would not be infringed by the generic drug.119

NDA or supplemental NDA (sNDA)120 sponsors who obtain approval for drugs that contain approved chemical entities, but are sufficiently changed from the approved drug (e.g., a new indication or formulation) to require additional clinical studies to be approved, are eligible for three years of data exclusivity running from the time of NDA approval.121 Unlike the five-year exclusivity for new chemical entities, FDA may accept ANDA and 505(b)(2) submissions that reference the changes meriting exclusivity during the three-year time period.122 The three-year exclusivity relates to when FDA may approve such applications.123 To obtain such three-year exclusivity, the NDA or sNDA must "contain[] reports of new clinical investigations (other than bioavailability studies)" that were "essential to the approval" of the application.124 In other words, the sponsor must have conducted or sponsored additional clinical trials that were necessary to obtain approval of the new drug in order to benefit from the three-year exclusivity for that new condition. As a result, three-year exclusivity is generally limited to new drugs that are significantly changed from approved drugs, rather than to minor modifications of those products.

For brand-name biological products, the BPCIA establishes two applicable periods of exclusivity. First, for new biological products (i.e., reference products), no biosimilar applications can be submitted for four years "after the date on which the reference product was first licensed."125 Second, approval of biosimilar applications cannot become effective until twelve years "after the date on which the reference product was first licensed."126 Together, these exclusivity periods mean that for the first four years after a reference biological product is licensed, FDA does not accept any biosimilar applications for review; for the next eight years, FDA accepts biosimilar applications for review, but it cannot approve any biosimilar application until twelve years after the date on which the reference product was first licensed. FDA has not adopted a formal position on whether these exclusivity periods are data or marketing exclusivity periods.127 Supplemental BLAs, for example to change the "indication, route of administration, dosing schedule, dosage form, delivery system, delivery device, or strength," are not eligible for these four- and twelve-year regulatory exclusivity periods.128

Generic Drug and Biosimilar Exclusivities

In addition to providing incentives for innovation, regulatory exclusivities are also used to promote competition by encouraging the entry of follow-on products. When an RLD has one or more patents listed in the Orange Book that have not expired, potential ANDA applicants have two choices: (1) wait until all listed patents have expired to apply for approval or (2) file a paragraph IV certification129 asserting that any active patents are invalid or would not be infringed by the generic product.130 The potential for ensuing patent litigation raises the anticipated costs for the first ANDA filer with a paragraph IV certification, as compared to subsequent ANDA filers.131 Accordingly, to incentivize generic manufacturers to be the first filer and to challenge listed patents purportedly covering an RLD, the Hatch-Waxman Act provides a 180-day exclusivity to the first ANDA applicant who successfully challenges an unexpired patent listed for the RLD using a paragraph IV certification, either by the RLD manufacturer declining to initiate litigation within forty-five days of receiving notice from the ANDA applicant of the paragraph IV certification or by obtaining a settlement or court ruling finding the challenged patent is invalid or not infringed.132 This exclusivity period precludes FDA from approving another ANDA for the same RLD during the 180-day period after the first commercial marketing of the generic drug.133 180-day exclusivity may be forfeited for a number of reasons, such as failing to commercially market the drug within a certain timeframe.134

The BPCIA similarly awards regulatory exclusivity to the first interchangeable biological product for a particular reference product.135 This exclusivity precludes FDA from making an interchangeability determination for a subsequent biologic relying on the same reference product for any condition of use until such exclusivity expires, the timing of which depends on the status of a relevant patent dispute.136 Specifically, the exclusivity period ends at the earlier of

  • one year after the commercial marketing of the first interchangeable product;
  • eighteen months after a final court decision in a patent infringement action against the first applicant or the dismissal of such an action;
  • forty-two months after approval if the first applicant has been sued and the litigation is still ongoing; or
  • eighteen months after approval if the first applicant has not been sued.137

Other Regulatory Exclusivities

There are also a number of regulatory exclusivities aimed at encouraging entry into markets that serve smaller or underserved populations or have limited competition. For example, Congress passed the Orphan Drug Act in 1983 to encourage development of drugs and biologics to treat rare diseases and conditions, called "orphan drugs."138 Because these drugs often treat small patient populations, and thus may provide fewer financial incentives for pharmaceutical manufacturers to develop them, the law (among other measures) provides a seven-year marketing exclusivity for companies that obtain approval for these drugs.139 During the seven-year period, FDA cannot approve an NDA or BLA for the same drug or biologic to treat the same disease or condition, even if the second applicant generates its own safety and efficacy data.140

To receive the orphan-drug exclusivity, (1) the drug must be intended to treat a "rare disease or condition,"141 and (2) FDA must not have previously approved the same drug "for the same use or indication."142 To meet the first condition, a sponsor may request, before submitting an NDA or BLA, that FDA designate its drug as one for a rare disease or condition.143 To designate an orphan drug, FDA must determine—when the designation is requested—the disease or condition the drug will treat "(A) affects less than 200,000 persons in the United States or (B) affects more than 200,000 in the United States and for which there is no reasonable expectation than the cost of developing and making available in the United States a drug for such disease or condition will be recovered from sales in the United States of such drug."144 Drugs so designated are entitled to the seven-year exclusivity if they also meet the second condition.

In addition, the FD&C Act provides a 180-day exclusivity to ANDAs for drugs designated by FDA (pursuant to the ANDA filer's request) as a "competitive generic therapy" (CGT) due to "inadequate generic competition."145 To receive the exclusivity, the ANDA must be the first filed for the CGT.146 The ANDA must also have been submitted when there were "no unexpired patents or exclusivities listed in the Orange Book for the relevant RLD."147 Finally, the applicant must commercially market the drug within seventy-five days of approval.148

To encourage manufacturers to evaluate the safety and effectiveness of their pharmaceutical products for children, NDA and BLA filers may obtain a pediatric exclusivity if FDA determines the drug or biological product "may produce health benefits" in the pediatric population and the filer completes pediatric studies at FDA's request.149 Pediatric exclusivity adds six months to any existing exclusivity the NDA or BLA filer has obtained.150 For example, if the NDA filer obtains a five-year exclusivity for a new active ingredient and conducts the requested pediatric studies, it is entitled to five and a half years of exclusivity.151

Table 1. Regulatory Exclusivities for Pharmaceutical Products

Type of Exclusivity

Length

Criteria

Effect

Drugs

     

New Chemical Entity

21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(E)(ii),

(j)(5)(F)(ii), (u)

5 years
(4 years if ANDA contains a paragraph IV certification)

Application for drug containing an active moiety that has never been approved; or application for a drug that contains as an active ingredient a single enantiomer (each of a pair of molecules that are mirror images of one another) of a previously approved racemic drug (a mixture of both enantiomers) that treats a different therapeutic category and does not rely on the racemic drug's data

FDA cannot accept an abbreviated application for the same active moiety that relies on the data in the reference drug application

New Clinical Investigation

21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(E)(iii)–(iv), (j)(5)(F)(iii)–(iv)

3 years

Application for a change to an approved drug that contains at least one new clinical investigation that is "essential to the approval" of the application and is conducted or sponsored by the applicant

FDA cannot approve an application that relies on the data in the reference drug application for 3 years

First to File Paragraph IV Certification

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv)

180 days

First to file an ANDA with a paragraph IV certification that a patent listed for the reference drug is invalid or not infringed by the generic product

FDA cannot approve an ANDA for the same drug until 180 days after first commercial marketing of first filer

Competitive Generic Therapy

21 U.S.C. §§ 355(j)(5)(B)(v), 356h(b)

180 days

Designation as competitive generic therapy by FDA based on finding of "inadequate generic competition" (only one active approved drug);

No unexpired patents or exclusivities for reference product

Once first approved applicant commences commercial marketing, FDA cannot approve an ANDA for the same reference product for 180 days after first commercial marketing

Biologics

     

Biologic Reference Product

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(7)(A), (B)

4 years (application) and 12 years (approval) after date of first licensure

First licensure of a biological product that is:

1. Not a supplemental application;

2. Not a change resulting in a new indication, route of administration, dosing schedule, dosage form, delivery system, delivery device, or strength; and

3. Not a modification to structure of product that does not result in a change in safety, purity, or potency

FDA cannot accept an abbreviated BLA referencing the product for first 4 years;

FDA cannot approve an abbreviated BLA referencing the product for 12 years

Interchangeable Biologic

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(6)

12–42 months (see Effects column)

First interchangeable biologic approved for a reference product;

Interchangeable means the product is biosimilar to the reference product, produces the same clinical result in any given patient, and a patient can switch between the interchangeable and reference products over multiple doses without altering risk

FDA cannot determine another product is interchangeable with the reference product for any condition of use until the earliest of: (1) 1 year after commercial marketing; (2) 18 months after approval if not sued; or (3) if sued, 18 months after decision or 42 months after approval

Other Purposes

     

Pediatric Studies

21 U.S.C. § 355a(b), (c)

42 U.S.C. § 262(m)

6 months

FDA requests that applicant conducts pediatric studies and such studies are completed

Extends other exclusivities by 6 months;

Delays approval for 6 months after listed patents expire

Orphan Drug

21 U.S.C. § 360cc

7 years

FDA designation as an orphan drug: a drug that treats a disease or condition that affects less than 200,000 people in the United States, or affects more than 200,000 people in the United States but there is no reasonable expectation that the cost of developing and making the drug would be recovered

FDA cannot approve another application for the same drug for the same disease or condition for 7 years, with limited exceptions

Qualified Infectious Disease Product

21 U.S.C. § 355f

5 years

FDA designation as a qualified infectious disease product (QIDP): an antibacterial or antifungal drug intended to treat serious or life-threatening infections, including those caused by qualifying or resistant pathogens

Extends other exclusivities by 5 years

Source: CRS.

Securing and Enforcing Patent Protections for Pharmaceuticals

Pharmaceutical manufacturers often seek to obtain patents on various aspects of their products. Congress's power to create the patent system derives from the IP Clause of the U.S. Constitution, which grants Congress the power "[t]o promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to . . . Inventors the exclusive Right to their . . . Discoveries."152 Congress has exercised this power since the early days of the Republic to make patent protection available to inventors.153 The currently operative patent statute is the Patent Act of 1952 (the Patent Act),154 as amended by laws such as the 2011 Leahy-Smith America Invents Act (AIA).155 This section overviews general patent law principles as they apply to pharmaceutical products, including common types of pharmaceutical patent claims, the legal rights granted to the holder of a valid patent, and the authority of the federal government to grant "compulsory licenses" for patents.

Patent Law Basics

Patents are generally available to anyone who invents a new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof. To obtain a patent, an inventor must file a patent application with the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO). A PTO patent examiner then evaluates the patent application to determine whether it meets all applicable statutory requirements to merit the grant of a patent. This process is called patent examination or patent prosecution.

To be patentable, the claimed invention must be (1) directed at patentable subject matter, (2) new, (3) nonobvious, and (4) useful. Although patentable subject matter is broad, federal courts have held that "products of nature" may not be patented, which may preclude patenting of unmodified biological material used in pharmaceuticals. The novelty and nonobviousness requirements preclude patenting inventions that are already known in the relevant field, or are a trivial variation on what is already known. The usefulness or utility requirement demands only that the invention have some practice use, and not that the invention be "better" than the state of existing technology.

Along with these substantive requirements relating to the invention, the Patent Act imposes several requirements relating to the form of the patent application and the technical information it provides about the claimed invention. Those provisions ensure that a granted patent adequately discloses the invention to the public so that anyone can use the invention after the patent term expires.

If granted, the patent's legal scope is defined by the patent claims. Patent claims must be sufficiently clear and definite to inform people skilled in the relevant technical field precisely what is covered by the patent, and what is not,

If granted, patents typically expire 20 years after the date the initial patent application was filed. During this time, no one else may make, use, sell, or import the invention in the United States without the permission of the patent holder. A person who practices the invention without the permission of the patent holder is said to infringe the patent and may be liable in court for monetary damages and other legal remedies.

Sources: 35 U.S.C. §§ 101, 102–103, 111–112, 154, 271; CRS Report R46525, Patent Law: A Handbook for Congress, coordinated by Kevin J. Hickey (2020).

Types of Pharmaceutical Patent Claims

To be patentable, like any other invention, pharmaceutical-related inventions must be new, useful, and nonobvious, and they must be sufficiently described in the patent application.156 While pharmaceutical-related inventions may take a variety of forms, there are several types of claims often made in connection with pharmaceutical products. For example, if a person is the first to synthesize a particular chemical that she believes to be useful for treating disease, she may obtain a patent on that chemical itself, generally referred to as the active ingredient.157 Manufacturers may find patents on a pharmaceutical product's active ingredient particularly valuable because these patents may be difficult to "invent around" (i.e., develop a competing product that does not infringe the patent).158 However, manufacturers of some biological products may not be able to patent unmodified naturally-occurring active ingredients if they are patent-ineligible subject matter.159

Manufacturers often obtain many other types of patents relating to a pharmaceutical product beyond active ingredient patents.160 Pharmaceutical patents may cover many different features of a drug or biologic beyond a claim on the active ingredient itself.161 Such patents may claim, among other things,

  • 1. formulations of a pharmaceutical (e.g., an administrable form and dosage, or a combination of active and other ingredients);
  • 2. methods of using the pharmaceutical (e.g., an indication or use of the drug for treating a particular disease);
  • 3. technologies and methods used to administer the pharmaceutical (e.g., an inhaler or injector device);
  • 4. technologies and methods for manufacturing the pharmaceutical (e.g., a manufacturing process);
  • 5. other chemicals related to the active ingredient, such as crystalline forms, polymorphs, intermediaries, salts, and metabolites.162

In addition, if a person invents an improvement on any of these technologies—for example, a new formulation of the drug, a new use for an existing drug, or a different manufacturing process—then the inventor can file for a patent on that improvement, which receives its own patent term.163 To be patentable, the improvement must be new and nonobvious, that is, "more than the predictable use of prior art elements according to their established functions."164 While it must be new and nonobvious, the "improvement" need not be actually better than the existing state of the art to be patentable.165 Any person wishing to practice the improved form of the invention would need permission from both the patent holder of the original technology and the holder of the improvement patent (who need not be the same entity), if neither patent has yet expired.166 If the original patent has expired but the improvement patent has not, permission from the improvement patentee is needed to practice the improved version, but as a matter of patent law, any person is free to make and use the original, unimproved version.167

Because many different aspects of pharmaceutical products (and improvements thereto) are patentable, dozens of different patents may protect some pharmaceutical products. On average, studies typically find that each drug in the Orange Book is associated with around three listed patents,168 although recent studies have found that this average has increased over the past decade.169 This number may understate the size of some pharmaceutical patent portfolios for several reasons: (1) only some patents relating to a drug may be included in the Orange Book;170 (2) most studies focus on chemical drugs and exclude biologics; and (3) there is evidence that patent portfolios tend to be larger for particularly lucrative pharmaceutical products.171 Studies that include biologics, non-Orange Book patents, or focus on top-selling products therefore tend to find larger average patent portfolios.172

To take one well known example, AbbVie obtained over 100 patents related to its biologic, Humira, covering various formulations, methods of using the biologic, methods of manufacturing the biologics, and the like.173 As discussed below, there is a significant public policy debate over such patent portfolios, particularly over the number, timing, and enforcement of nonactive ingredient patents (sometimes called "secondary" patents).174

Patent Enforcement

Rights of Patent Holders

Once granted, the holder of a valid patent has the exclusive right to make, use, sell, or import the invention in the United States until the patent expires.175 Any other person who practices the invention (i.e., makes, uses, sells, offers to sell, or imports it) without permission from the patent holder infringes the patent and is liable for monetary damages, and possibly injunctive relief, if sued by the patentee.176 Patents have the attributes of personal property, so the patentee may sell or assign the patent to another person.177 A patentee may also license other persons to practice the invention, granting them permission to make, use, sell, or import the invention, usually in exchange for consideration (such as monetary royalties).178

Patents thus provide a negative right to prevent another person from practicing the claimed invention. But patents do not grant the patentee any affirmative right to practice the invention.179 In the pharmaceutical context, this means that even if a manufacturer has a patent on a particular drug (or inventions related to making or using that drug), it still cannot market that drug without FDA approval.180

Patents are not self-enforcing: to obtain relief from infringement, the patentee must typically sue in court.181 Patent law is an area of exclusive federal jurisdiction,182 and the traditional forum for most patent disputes is federal district court.183 Although patent suits may be filed in any district court across the country with jurisdiction over the defendant and proper venue,184 all appeals in patent cases are heard by a single specialized court, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit.185

Patent Term and Effective Exclusivity Periods

With some exceptions, a patent is granted "for a term beginning on the date on which the patent issues and ending 20 years from the date on which the application for the patent was filed."186 The Patent Act includes provisions that may modify the 20-year term, including to account for excessive delays in patent examination at the PTO,187 or delays associated with obtaining marketing approval from other federal agencies (including FDA).188 In the pharmaceutical context, the PTO may extend the term of patents claiming a drug product or medical device (or a method of using or manufacturing the same) for up to five years to account for delays in obtaining regulatory approval, if certain statutory conditions are met.189

Precisely when generic or biosimilar competition occurs for any given product depends on a complex interplay of market incentives, patents, regulatory exclusivities, FDA processes, and—not infrequently—litigation.190 New drugs and biologics are commonly protected by both patents and FDA regulatory exclusivities. Although patents can last up to 20 years, some of the patent term is taken up by the patent application process itself or occurs prior to market approval for a drug or biologic, particularly for patents granted early in a product's life cycle.191 In addition, although patents carry a presumption of validity,192 they may be challenged by generic and biosimilar manufacturers, as discussed in detail below.193

In practice, empirical studies usually find that the average effective market exclusivity period for new drugs (i.e., the average time before actual generic entry) is between 12 and 15 years.194 Although data is limited, some studies show that average effective exclusivity periods are longer for biologics.195 This may be due to market and patenting factors, or the longer general regulatory exclusivity period (12 years) for new biologics.196

Defenses to Claims of Patent Infringement

Parties accused of patent infringement may defend on several grounds. First, although patents are subject to a presumption of validity, the accused infringer may assert that the patent is invalid.197 To prove invalidity, the accused infringer must show, by clear and convincing evidence, that the PTO should not have granted the patent because it failed to meet the requirements for patentability.198 Thus, for example, the accused infringer may argue that the invention lacks novelty, is obvious, or claims nonpatentable subject matter; that the patent fails to sufficiently describe or enable the invention; or that the patent claims are indefinite.199 Second, the accused infringer may argue that it is not liable based on noninfringement.200 In other words, even presuming the patent is valid, the patentee may fail to prove that the actions of the accused infringer fall within the scope of the patent claims.201 Finally, the accused infringer may argue the patent is unenforceable based on the patent holder's inequitable or illegal activities, such as obtaining the patent through fraud on the PTO.202

Remedies for Patent Infringement

If the patentee succeeds in proving infringement, the patent holder may obtain two major forms of judicial relief: monetary damages and injunctive relief.203 Damages must be "adequate to compensate for the infringement."204 Typically, courts will award either (1) lost profits (the net revenue "lost to the patentee because of the infringement"),205 or (2) a reasonable royalty (the amount the patentee would have received in a "hypothetical negotiation" if the patentee and the infringer had negotiated a good-faith license).206 Courts may increase these damages "up to three times the amount found or assessed,"207 but such enhanced damages are "generally reserved for egregious cases of culpable behavior" by the infringer.208 Finally, courts may award attorneys' fees in "exceptional cases"209 that "stand[] out from others with respect to the substantive strength of a party's litigating position" or "the unreasonable manner in which the case was litigated."210

A patent holder may also ask a court to order various forms of injunctive relief.211 At the outset of a patent litigation, a patent holder may seek a preliminary injunction, a court order that prevents the defendant from committing the allegedly infringing acts while the litigation proceeds.212 If a patentee prevails in an infringement lawsuit, the patent holder may seek a permanent injunction, a final order prohibiting the defendant from infringing the patent in the future.213

The Patent Trial and Appeal Board

Following its creation through the AIA in 2011, the PTO's Patent Trial and Appeal Board (PTAB) has become an increasingly important forum for patent disputes.214 The AIA created several new administrative procedures for challenging patent validity,215 including (1) post-grant review (PGR), which allows petitioners to challenge patent validity based on any of the requirements of patentability if the PGR petition is filed within nine months of the patent's issuance;216 and (2) inter partes review (IPR), which allows any person other than the patentee to challenge patent validity on limited grounds (novelty or obviousness based on prior patents or printed publications) at any time after nine months following the patent's issuance.217 PTAB may institute a PGR or IPR when a petition filed with PTAB establishes a reasonable likelihood that the petitioner would prevail with respect to at least one of the claims challenged (although the PTAB retains discretion to deny a petition).218 Of these two procedures, IPR is by far the most widely used.219

According to a PTO analysis, the majority of IPR petitions concern patents on computer and electronical technologies.220 About 4% of IPR petitions filed between 2012 and 2023 concern patents listed in the Orange Book, with an additional 2% concerning biologic patents.221 These averages are down in recent years from a FY2016 peak of 7.5% IPR petitions challenging Orange Book patents, and a peak of 3.9% of IPRs challenging biologic patents in FY2017.222 IPR petitions challenging drug and biologic patents are instituted at lower rates than the overall average.223

Compulsory Licensing

As explained above, a patent holder generally has the exclusive right to practice an invention. Any other person who wishes to make, use, sell, or import the invention would ordinarily need a license (i.e., permission) from the patent holder, or else be exposed to legal liability.224 In certain cases, however, patents may be subject to a "compulsory license," which allows another person to use the invention without the patent holder's prior consent.225

Compulsory licenses are typically authorized by statute and usually require the sanction of a governmental entity and payment of compensation to the patent holder.226 Compulsory licenses differ from ordinary patent licenses in two important respects: (1) the person seeking to use the invention need not seek advance permission from the patent holder; and (2) the compensation paid to the patentee is generally determined by operation of law, not by private contractual negotiations between the licensee and the patent holder.

Current federal law contains several provisions that may be characterized as compulsory licenses for patents.227 One, 28 U.S.C. § 1498, is sometimes described as an "eminent domain" provision for patents.228 Section 1498 allows the U.S. government to use any patented invention "without license."229 The patentee, however, has the right to sue in the U.S. Court of Federal Claims for "reasonable and entire compensation" for the government's use of the patented invention.230 A court, though, would not issue an injunction against the United States to prevent its use of the invention.231 In effect, then, section 1498 allows the United States to issue itself a compulsory license to use any patented invention without obtaining the patentee's permission in exchange for the payment of reasonable compensation.232 This compulsory license may extend to federal contractors, subcontractors, and any person acting "with the authorization or consent of the [U.S.] Government."233 The federal government relies on section 1498 authority with some frequency,234 particularly in the defense context.235 In the pharmaceutical context, however, the United States has not used section 1498 in recent decades.236

Compulsory licensing is also available for inventions made with federal funding under the Bayh-Dole Act.237 In general, Bayh-Dole permits certain government contractors to obtain patents on inventions produced with federal funding.238 However, the federal government retains the authority to "march in" and grant compulsory licenses to third parties for federally funded inventions under certain specified circumstances, such as the patent holder's failure to practice the patented invention or health or safety needs.239 A license granted under Bayh-Dole's march-in provisions must be "upon terms that are reasonable under the circumstances," which may require the licensee to pay some compensation to the patentee.240 The federal government has never exercised its march-in rights under Bayh-Dole.241

Some stakeholders and Members of Congress have urged the federal government to make greater use of these compulsory licensing authorities as a means to authorize generic competition and potentially lower prices for certain drugs.242 Others argue that these statutory authorities do not support compulsory licensing as a means to control drug prices, or that using them in this way would undermine incentives for innovation in drug development.243 In December 2023, the National Institute of Standards and Technology (which has relevant regulatory authority to implement the Bayh-Dole Act) published draft guidance suggesting that agencies may consider the patented product's price, among other factors, when deciding whether to exercise march-in rights.244 The Biden Administration touted the draft guidance as a way to promote competition and lower prescription drug costs.245 Critics contended that Bayh-Dole does not permit agencies to consider pricing and that the potential use of march-in rights would undermine pharmaceutical innovation and investment in R&D.246

Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs and Biosimilars

As Table 2 summarizes, patent rights granted by the PTO and regulatory exclusivities granted by FDA are legally distinct.247 They are motivated by similar purposes. Patents seek to encourage innovation by providing an economic incentive for inventors to invest their time and resources in developing novel inventions.248 Analogously, regulatory exclusivities granted by FDA249 provide an incentive for pharmaceutical manufacturers to undertake the investments necessary to complete the FDA approval process and bring new drugs and biologics to market.250

In some circumstances, patent rights can affect when a manufacturer can market a generic drug or biosimilar. For example, if a court hearing a patent dispute grants an injunction that prohibits a manufacturer from infringing by making a generic drug, the manufacturer cannot bring that product to market until after the patent expires and the injunction terminates.251 In addition, as discussed below, the Hatch-Waxman Act's specialized patent dispute procedures can affect FDA's ability to approve an ANDA, even prior to a judicial decision.252 Patent rights may also affect follow-on market entry indirectly, if a generic or biosimilar manufacturer declines to seek FDA approval because of the number of existing patents relating to a product or the anticipated costs of challenging them.253

Table 2. Summary Comparison of Patents Versus Regulatory Exclusivities

 

Patents

Regulatory Exclusivities

Purpose

Provide incentives to encourage creation of new technologies

Balance pharmaceutical innovation and generic competition

Specific to Pharmaceuticals?

No; available to any "process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter"

Yes

Relevant Agency

Patent & Trademark Office (PTO)

Food & Drug Administration (FDA)

Requirements

New, useful, nonobvious, and sufficiently disclosed invention

Completion of FDA regulatory process for a particular drug or biological product

Term

Generally 20 years from the date the relevant patent application was filed

Variable (six months to 12 years) based on drug type, prior approvals, and other factors

Effect

Third parties cannot make, use, sell, or import the invention without the patentee's permission

Third parties cannot seek, obtain, and/or use data for FDA approval with respect to particular product

Enforcement

By the patentee, usually through a patent infringement lawsuit

By FDA

Source: CRS.

Rationale for Specialized Pharmaceutical Patent Procedures

One of the core aims of the Hatch-Waxman Act was to correct "two unintended distortions" in the patent term resulting from the patent law's interaction with FDA premarketing requirements for drugs and biologics.254 The first distortion affected new drug manufacturers: because obtaining FDA marketing approval may take years, regulatory requirements shorten the effective patent term (i.e., the period during which the patentee can derive profit from the invention).255 In response, the Hatch-Waxman Act granted a patent term extension for certain inventions relating to drug products or medical devices based on delays in obtaining regulatory marketing approval.256

The other distortion concerned the end of the patent term and affected generic-drug manufacturers. In general, once a patent expires, the patented invention should be available for anyone to use.257 In the pharmaceutical context, generic manufacturers should, in theory, be able to enter the market shortly after the applicable patents and regulatory exclusivities have expired. Prior to the Hatch-Waxman Act, however, some judicial decisions held that uses of a patented drug necessary to obtain FDA approval, such as conducting tests on a patented drug, constituted patent infringement.258 Thus, as a practical matter, generic manufacturers could often not even begin seeking FDA approval until the applicable patents expired.259 The result was an "effective extension of the patent term" based on the "combined effect of the patent law and the premarket regulatory approval requirement."260 In response, the Hatch-Waxman Act created a "safe harbor," providing that making, using, or selling an invention "solely for uses reasonably related to the development and submission of information under a federal law which regulates the manufacture, use, or sale of drugs" is not patent infringement.261

A potential side effect of this safe harbor was to limit the ability of a pharmaceutical patent holder to file a lawsuit for patent infringement prior to the generic manufacturer's marketing of the follow-on product.262 If actions relating to the FDA approval process are no longer infringing, patent litigation against an ANDA filer might not occur until the generic or biosimilar is marketed, after the completion of the FDA approval process.263 Earlier resolution of patent disputes is usually regarded as beneficial, as it provides greater legal certainty to both the brand-name and generic-drug manufacturers.264 In particular, generic manufacturers can obtain clarity on patent issues before they market a drug and expose themselves to monetary damages.265

To facilitate early patent dispute resolution, the Hatch-Waxman Act made the filing of an ANDA or paper NDA an "artificial" act of patent infringement.266 The BPCIA contains an analogous provision making the filing of a biosimilar or interchangeable BLA an artificial act of patent infringement.267 Functionally, these artificial acts of infringement enable the brand-name manufacturer to sue for patent infringement at the time of the follow-on application, allowing litigation of patent disputes before the generic drug or biosimilar is marketed.268

For all these reasons, both the Hatch-Waxman Act and the BPCIA enacted specialized patent dispute resolution procedures that complement the abbreviated pathways for the regulatory approval for follow-on products. This section reviews these procedures.

The Hatch-Waxman Act: Patents and Generic Drug Approval

Paragraph I-IV Certifications and Interaction with FDA Approval

Under the Hatch-Waxman Act, a drug manufacturer must list, as part of its NDA, any patent that claims the drug that is the subject of the application, or a method of using that drug.269 FDA includes information on listed patents in the Orange Book.270 When a generic drug manufacturer files an ANDA, it must provide a certification for each patent listed in the Orange Book for the RLD.271 Figure 1 diagrams the patent dispute process under the Hatch-Waxman Act.

In particular, with some exceptions,272 the generic applicant must make one of four certifications for each listed patent:

(I) there is no patent information listed;

(II) the patent has expired;

(III) the date the patent will expire; or

(IV) the patent is invalid or not infringed by the generic applicant's product.273

Paragraph I and II certifications do not affect FDA's ability to approve the ANDA.274 If the generic applicant makes a paragraph III certification, FDA may not approve the ANDA until the patent at issue has expired.275

A paragraph IV certification triggers Hatch-Waxman's specialized patent dispute procedures, often leading to litigation.276 First, the generic applicant must give notice of the ANDA and the paragraph IV certification to the patentee and the NDA holder, including "a detailed statement of the factual and legal basis" for patent invalidity or noninfringement.277 The NDA or patent holder then has 45 days to sue the generic applicant for patent infringement.278 If the NDA or patent holder declines to sue by the deadline, the generic applicant may file a "civil action to obtain patent certainty" to obtain a declaratory judgment that the Orange Book-listed patents are invalid or not infringed.279

If the patent holder timely files suit after being notified of the paragraph IV certification, this lawsuit triggers the "30-month stay": FDA generally cannot approve the ANDA for 30 months while the parties litigate their patent dispute.280 If, before the expiration of the 30-month stay, the district court concludes the patent is invalid or not infringed by the ANDA filer, FDA may approve the ANDA as of the date of the court's judgment or a settlement order to that effect.281 If the court finds the patent is infringed (and the ANDA filer does not appeal that decision), then the effective date of ANDA approval must be "not earlier than the date of the expiration of the patent which has been infringed."282 FDA approval of a generic drug application can thus be significantly delayed based on patent rights asserted by the NDA holder.

Figure 1. Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs

The Hatch-Waxman Notice-and-Certification Process

media/image4.png

Source: CRS.

Orange Book Patent Listings

By statute, NDA filers must list patents that either (1) "claim[] the drug" that is the subject of the NDA or (2) claim "a method of using such drug."283 FDA regulations make clear that "drug substance (active ingredient) patents, drug product (formulation and composition) patents, and method-of-use patents" must be listed, while "[p]rocess patents, patents claiming packaging, patents claiming metabolites, and patents claiming intermediates" must not be listed.284 As a result, patents on a process for manufacturing a drug, for example, should not be included in the NDA or listed in the Orange Book. (Because only certain patents relating to a drug are listed in the Orange Book, some patent litigation concerning generic drugs takes place outside the specialized notice-and-certification procedures of the Hatch-Waxman Act.)

FDA does not actively police the patent information listed in the Orange Book, viewing its role as merely "ministerial."285 This approach has raised concerns among some commentators that NDA holders may list inapplicable patents in the Orange Book as a means to deter generic competition.286 FDA does offer an administrative process through which "any person [who] disputes the accuracy or relevance of patent information" in the Orange Book, or believes that an NDA holder "has failed to submit required patent information," may notify the Agency and seek correction of the patent information.287 With the availability of the 30-month stay and the requirement that ANDA filers make a certification for each patent listed in the Orange Book, it is generally in the interest of NDA holders to list all potentially relevant patents.288 There is no statutory provision providing that the patentee or NDA holder forfeits the right to sue if she fails to list the applicable patents, however.289

Given the advantages of listing patents in the Orange Book and the FDA's ministerial approach to policing patents listed in the Orange Book, NDA holders and generic manufactures sometimes dispute whether certain types are pharmaceutical patents were properly listed by NDA holders in the Orange Book. For example, generic drug manufacturers have made successful legal challenges to device patents and patents relating to risk evaluation and mitigation strategies (REMS) as improperly included in the Orange Book.290 In 2022, FDA released a report collecting public comments on patent information in the Orange Book and indicated that it has convened a working group to "evaluate whether additional clarity is needed regarding the types of patents, patent information, or other patent-related information that should be included in, or removed from, the Orange Book, consistent with the current statutory requirements."291

In 2023, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) issued a policy statement concerning brand-name drug manufacturers' "improper listing of patents" in the Orange Book.292 The intent of the statement was to "put market participants on notice that the FTC intends to scrutinize improper Orange Book listings to determine whether these constitute unfair methods of competition in violation of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act."293 FTC observed that improperly listed patents "may disincentivize investments in developing a competing product and increase the risk of delayed generic and follow-on product entry, reducing patient access to more affordable prescription drugs and increasing costs to the healthcare system."294 A few months later, FTC announced that it had invoked FDA's regulatory process to challenge more than 100 patents as improperly listed in the Orange Book, including patents relating to drug-delivery devices such as asthma inhalers and epinephrine autoinjectors.295

Section viii Statements and "Skinny Labels"

For patents that claim a method of using a drug (as opposed to a claim on the drug itself), FDA regulations require NDA holders to include a description of listed method-of-use patents, including information on whether the patent claims one or more FDA-approved methods of using the drug.296 This description must be "adequate" to assist potential ANDA filers in determining whether a listed patent covers a particular approved use or indication.297 The NDA holder must also identify the sections of the approved drug label that describe the method(s) of use claimed by that patent.298 FDA uses this information to create use codes for method-of-use patents, which are also listed in the Orange Book.299 As with all patent information in the Orange Book, FDA does not independently verify the accuracy of use codes, but instead merely publishes the information submitted to it by NDA holders.300

When one approved method of using the drug is still covered by a patent, but another use is unpatented or no longer patented, the Hatch-Waxman Act allows ANDA applicants to file a "section viii statement" instead of a paragraph I–IV certification with respect to that method-of-use patent.301 In a section viii statement, the ANDA filer avers that it is not seeking approval for the patented use, but only for other approved uses of the drug not covered by the patent.302 The ANDA filer must also submit proposed labeling that omits the portions of the brand-name drug's label corresponding to the still-patented use.303 For this reason, generics relying on section viii statements are said to "carve out" the patented use, resulting in a "skinny label."304 Unlike a paragraph III or IV certification, a section viii statement does not delay FDA's ability to approve the ANDA.305

Some stakeholders question whether the Hatch-Waxman Act's skinny-label provisions are effective in facilitating partial generic competition when some, but not all, uses of a drug are patented. Because the FDA does not independently verify use-code accuracy, an "overly broad" use code (and the limited ability for generics to challenge use codes) may interfere with an ANDA applicant's ability to use section viii statements.306 In addition, because generics relying on the skinny-label procedure may still be sued for induced patent infringement based on the purportedly carved out uses,307 the pathway may carry some risk for generic manufacturers.308

The BPCIA: The "Patent Dance" and Biosimilar Licensure

A different patent dispute resolution scheme applies to biological products and biosimilars, which are subject to regulatory licensure under the PHSA, as amended by the BPCIA.309 Unlike the Hatch-Waxman approach, FDA's licensure of biosimilars under the BPCIA is not directly contingent on resolution of patent disputes, and a BLA filer need not list patent information as part of its BLA.310 Under the Purple Book Continuity Act of 2020, BLA holders are required to provide to FDA information on patents asserted against a biosimilar company during the so-called "patent dance" discussed below.311 As a result, the "Purple Book"—FDA's list of approved biological products that is the biologics analogue of the Orange Book—contains only limited patent information.312

Instead of the Hatch-Waxman Act's certification process, patent disputes over biosimilars may be resolved through the BPCIA's patent dance.313 The patent dance is "a carefully calibrated scheme for preparing to adjudicate, and then adjudicating, claims of infringement" by reference product sponsors (i.e., the brand-name biologic manufacturers) against biosimilar applicants.314 Depending on their participation in the patent dance, each party has an opportunity to litigate relevant patents in two phases. The first ("phase one") is at the conclusion of the patent dance—roughly six months after the biosimilar applicant files its BLA.315 The second ("phase two") is when the biosimilar applicant provides a notice of commercial marketing, no later than 180 days before the date the biosimilar will be marketed.316

The first step in the patent dance process occurs when, not later than 20 days after FDA accepts a biosimilar BLA, the biosimilar applicant provides its application to the reference product sponsor, along with information on how the biosimilar is manufactured.317 "These disclosures enable the [reference product] sponsor to evaluate the biosimilar for possible infringement of patents it holds on the reference product (i.e., the corresponding biologic)."318 The biosimilar applicant and reference product sponsor next engage in a series of back-and-forth information exchanges regarding the patents that each party believes are relevant, as well as the parties' positions on the validity and infringement of those patents.319 No later than 60 days after the initial disclosure by the biosimilar applicant, the reference product sponsor provides a list of patents that it reasonably believes it could assert, and whether it is willing to license them.320 No later than 60 days thereafter, the biosimilar applicant provides its factual and legal basis for why the patents are invalid or not infringed, or whether it would accept a license.321 After the reference product sponsor responds to the biosimilar applicant's invalidity and infringement contentions,322 the parties engage in "good faith negotiations" over which patents (and how many) should be litigated immediately.323 Once the parties determine the set of patents for "phase one" litigation, the reference product sponsor has 30 days to bring an action for infringement of those patents.324

"Phase two" litigation under the BPCIA begins once the biosimilar applicant gives notice to the reference product sponsor "not later than 180 days" before the first commercial marketing of the biosimilar product.325 After receiving this notice, the reference product sponsor may seek a preliminary injunction for infringement of patents that were included on its initial patent list but not selected for phase-one litigation.326 The biosimilar applicant may choose to give this "phase two" notice prior to FDA licensure of the biosimilar, so long as the notice is given 180 days before commercial marketing.327 Thus, the biosimilar applicant can opt to "collapse" the two phases of litigation, if it so chooses.328

Reference product sponsors cannot obtain injunctive relief to compel the biosimilar applicant to engage in the patent dance.329 In practice, this limitation means that biosimilar applicants can choose whether or not they wish to engage in the patent dance. If the biosimilar applicant chooses not to commence the patent dance, the BPCIA "authorizes the [reference product] sponsor, but not the applicant, to bring an immediate declaratory-judgment action for artificial [patent] infringement."330 Thus, although the biosimilar applicant need not immediately reveal its manufacturing information if it chooses not to commence the patent dance, it exposes itself to an immediate declaratory-judgment lawsuit for patent infringement.331 Biosimilar applicants thus may face complicated strategic tradeoffs in deciding whether to initiate the patent dance.332

Unlike patent listings in the Orange Book under the Hatch-Waxman Act, the BPCIA contains an express statutory penalty for failing to list relevant patents during the patent dance. If the biosimilar applicant commences the patent dance, the reference product sponsor must provide a list of all "patents for which the reference product sponsor believes a claim of patent infringement could reasonably be asserted. . . if a person not licensed by the reference product sponsor engaged in the making, using, offering to sell, selling, or importing [of the biological product at issue]."333 Under the "list it or lose it" requirement, the patent holder may forfeit his right to sue on patents that are not included on this list.334 Specifically, if a patent "should have been included in the list [as required during the patent dance], but was not timely included in such list," then the patent owner "may not bring an action under this section for infringement of the patent with respect to the biological product."335

Figure 2 diagrams the general patent dispute process under the BPCIA's patent dance. Table 3 summarizes the key differences between the patent dispute resolution regimes for drugs under the Hatch-Waxman Act and for biologics under the BPCIA.

Figure 2. Patent Dispute Procedures for Biosimilars

The BPCIA "Patent Dance"

media/image5.png

Source: CRS.

Table 3. Summary Comparison of the Hatch-Waxman Act and the BPCIA

Follow-on Regulatory Pathways and Patent Dispute Procedures

Feature

Hatch-Waxman and Generic Drug Approval

BPCIA and Biosimilar (or Interchangeable) Licensure

Regulatory Statute

FD&C Act

PHSA

Scope

A "drug" is, inter alia, a chemical compound "intended for use in the diagnosis, cure, mitigation, treatment, or prevention of disease" (21 U.S.C. § 321(g)(1))

A "biologic" is a medical product derived from natural sources (human, animal, microorganism) and applicable to the prevention, treatment, or cure of disease (42 U.S.C. § 262(i)(1)

Example

Aspirin: C9H8O4

Adalimumab (a.k.a. Humira): C6428H9912N1694O1987S46

Terminology

Drug is approved by FDA

Biological product is licensed by FDA

General Regulatory Standard

Safe and effective

Safe, pure, and potent

New Product Pathway

New drug application (NDA) (21 U.S.C. § 355(b))

Biologics license application (BLA) (42 U.S.C. § 262(a))

Abbreviated Pathway

Abbreviated new drug application (ANDA) (21 U.S.C. § 355(j))

Biosimilar (or interchangeable) BLA (42 U.S.C. § 262(k))

Relationship Between New and Follow-on Product

Chemical identity: the active ingredient of the new drug is "the same as" that of the listed drug (if only one ingredient) (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(ii))

Biosimilarity: "highly similar to the reference product" without "clinically meaningful differences" (42 U.S.C. § 262(i)(2); see also 42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(4) (interchangeability))

General Exclusivity Term for New Product

5-year new chemical entity exclusivity (3 years for other new products)

12-year new biologic exclusivity

Follow-On Exclusivity

180-day patent challenge exclusivity or 180-day competitive generic exclusivity

12- to 42-month exclusivity for first interchangeable product

Patent Listing Requirements

Required to list in NDA any patent that "claims the drug or a method of using the drug" (21 C.F.R. § 314.53(b); 21 U.S.C. § 355(b)(1))

Not required to list patents in BLA.

If patent dance is initiated, BLA holder must list all patents "for which the [BLA holder] believes a claim of patent infringement could reasonably be asserted" (42 U.S.C. § 262(l)(3)(A)(i))

Patent Listing Consequences

ANDA filer need not certify; NDA loses opportunity for 30-month stay

"List it or lose it" (35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(6)(C))

FDA List of Approved Products

The Orange Book

The Purple Book

Patent Dispute Procedures

Patent Certification/Notice (21 U.S.C. § 355(b)(2)–(3), (c)(3), (j)(2)(A)–(B), (j)(5))

The "Patent Dance" (42 U.S.C. § 262(l))

Approval Contingent on Patent Disputes?

Yes, e.g., via the 30-month stay

No

Source: CRS.

Antitrust Law

How some drug and biologic manufacturers have obtained and enforced their patents may raise issues under federal antitrust laws. The Supreme Court has stated that the "primary purpose of the antitrust laws" is to protect and promote competition "from which lower prices can later result."336 To this end, antitrust law generally aims to "prevent[] anticompetitive conduct that enables firms to exercise market power."337 The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 (the Sherman Act) contains two provisions that prohibit agreements in restraint of trade and monopolization, respectively.338 As discussed below, certain pharmaceutical patenting practices have been challenged by follow-on manufacturers under each of these two sections.339

Section 1 of the Sherman Act

Section 1 of the Sherman Act bars "[e]very contract, combination . . . , or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce."340 Although that language appears to sweep broadly, the Supreme Court has interpreted Section 1 to only bar unreasonable restraints on trade.341 In evaluating the reasonableness of contractual restraints on trade under Section 1, courts have found that "some agreements and practices are invalid per se, while others are illegal only as applied to particular situations."342 Unless the agreement falls within a per se illegal category, courts generally apply a "rule-of-reason" analysis to determine whether a restraint on trade is reasonable.

Per Se Illegal. Certain agreements are considered per se illegal "without regard to a consideration of their reasonableness"343 because "the probability that these practices are anticompetitive is so high."344 Only restraints that "have manifestly anticompetitive effects" and lack "any redeeming virtue" are held to be per se illegal.345 Examples of per se illegal restraints include agreements for horizontal price fixing, market allocations, and output limitations.346 To prevail on a claim of a per se illegal agreement, the plaintiff need only demonstrate that the agreement in question falls in one of the per se categories; in other words, "liability attaches without need for proof of power, intent or impact."347

The Rule-of-Reason Analysis. Challenged restraints that are not in the per se illegal category are generally analyzed under the rule-of-reason approach. While the Supreme Court has not developed a canonical framework to guide this totality-of-the-circumstances reasonableness inquiry, most courts take a similar approach in resolving rule-of-reason cases.348 Under this burden-shifting approach, a Section 1 plaintiff has the initial burden of demonstrating that a challenged restraint has anticompetitive effects in a "properly defined product" and geographic market—that is, that the restraint causes higher prices, reduced output, or diminished quality in the relevant market.349 If the plaintiff succeeds in making this showing, the burden then shifts to the defendant to rebut the plaintiff's evidence with a procompetitive justification for the challenged practice.350 If the defendant adequately demonstrates a procompetitive justification, the burden then shifts back to the plaintiff to show either (1) the restraint's anticompetitive effects outweigh its procompetitive effects or (2) the restraint's procompetitive effects could be achieved in a manner that is less restrictive of competition.351

Quick Look Analysis. In certain instances, courts may use "something of a sliding scale in appraising reasonableness," applying a more abbreviated rule-of-reason analysis to an agreement, referred to as a "quick look."352 In identifying this intermediate standard of review, the Supreme Court explained that, because "[t]here is always something of a sliding scale in appraising reasonableness," the "quality of proof required" to establish a Section 1 violation "should vary with the circumstances."353 As a result, the Court has concluded that in certain cases—specifically, those in which "no elaborate industry analysis is required to demonstrate the anticompetitive character" of a challenged agreement—plaintiffs can establish a prima facie case that an agreement is anticompetitive without presenting the sort of market power evidence traditionally required at the first step of the rule-of-reason analysis.354

Section 2 of the Sherman Act

Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes it unlawful to monopolize, attempt to monopolize, or conspire to monopolize "any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations."355 Despite the facially broad language of Section 2, the Supreme Court has clarified that monopolization is only illegal if "it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct."356 It is not illegal to possess monopoly power that is the result of, for example, "a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident."357 Thus, establishing a Section 2 violation requires proving the defendant "possessed monopoly power in the relevant market" and acquired or maintained that power using anticompetitive conduct.358 Courts generally analyze whether conduct is anticompetitive (i.e., step two of the analysis) using a rule-of-reason approach.359

Enforcement

Federal civil antitrust laws are primarily enforced through three mechanisms: (1) enforcement actions brought by the U.S. Department of Justice's Antitrust Division, (2) enforcement actions brought FTC, or (3) lawsuits brought by a private party or by a state attorney general on behalf of a private party.360 In particular, Section 5 of the FTC Act gives the FTC authority to combat "[u]nfair methods of competition" generally, which includes violations of the Sherman Act.361

FTC enforcement typically begins with a confidential investigation into the relevant conduct.362 A company may resolve the investigation by entering into a consent order agreeing to stop or to address the potentially anticompetitive practices.363 If the FTC and the company do not reach a consent order, the FTC may begin an administrative proceeding or may seek relief in the federal courts.364 The administrative proceeding is similar to a court proceeding, but is overseen by an administrative law judge (ALJ).365 If the ALJ finds that there has been a violation, the FTC may issue a cease-and-desist order. The ALJ's decision is appealable to the full FTC, then to a U.S. Court of Appeals and, finally, to the Supreme Court.366

Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices

Patent holders generally seek to use their rights to the fullest extent permitted by law, regardless of their patent's technological field.367 From the patent holders' perspective, the practices described below may be viewed as appropriate uses of the legal rights granted by their patents, which were obtained after a rigorous examination process that demonstrated compliance with patentability requirements.368 Critics, on the other hand, view these practices as harmful strategies that exploit the patent system in ways Congress did not intend.369

This section discusses four alleged patenting practices that have created controversy and—in some cases—led to proposed legislative reforms.

First, commentators allege that some pharmaceutical companies obtain new patents to cover a product as older patents expire to extend the period of exclusivity without significant benefits for consumers, a practice referred to as "evergreening."370

Second, commentators also contend that pharmaceutical manufacturers engage in "product hopping" by attempting to switch or "hop" consumers to a slightly different product covered by a later-expiring patent, just as the patent covering a current product nears expiration.371

Third, commentators argue that pharmaceutical companies have allegedly acquired many overlapping patents on a single product, creating so-called "patent thickets."372 Critics allege these patent "thickets" may deter potential competitors, even if the patents are weak or invalid, due to the time, expense, and uncertainty of challenging many patents.373

Finally, brand and generic pharmaceutical companies will often settle litigation that results when a generic seeks to compete with a patented branded product.374 Certain settlement agreements transfer value from the brand to the generic in return for the generic delaying its market entry.375 Some characterize such "pay-for-delay" or "reverse payment" settlements as anticompetitive because they may delay cheaper generic drugs from entering the market, thereby allowing the brand to maintain its exclusivity period on a patent that otherwise may have been invalidated, benefiting the settling companies at the expense of consumers.376

"Evergreening"

Definition

Evergreening, also known as patent "layering" or "life-cycle management," is a practice by which drug innovators allegedly seek "to prolong their effective periods of patent protection through ... strategies that add new patents to their quivers as old ones expire."377 As discussed above, because different aspects of pharmaceutical products (and improvements thereon) are patentable,378 dozens of different patents can protect a single pharmaceutical product. The average number of patents per drug has steadily increased since the Hatch-Waxman Act became law in 1984.379 On average, there are about 3 patents listed for each pharmaceutical product listed in the Orange Book.380

Particularly profitable drugs are usually protected by more patents than average,381 and some of those patents may be added to the Orange Book relatively late in the life cycle of a drug (as opposed to when a new drug has just come to market). Because later-issued patents generally have later expiration dates (presuming they arise from a later patent application), these later patents, if valid, may extend the total effective exclusivity period for a drug or biologic. One comprehensive study of evergreening found that 78% of the drugs that had new patents added to their Orange Book listing were for existing drugs—not new market drugs just coming to market—and that such "evergreening" was particularly common for best-selling drugs.382

For example, a 2020 report from the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Oversight and Reform investigated the pricing of Revlimid, a top-selling plasma cell myeloma drug made by Celgene Corporation.383 The staff report concluded that Celgene "stifled generic competition by filing for" numerous patents—including ten patents on Revlimid's REMS program—"and enforcing those patents against potential generic competitors."384 Another House Committee on Oversight and Reform investigation into Amgen's biologic Enbrel, used to treat rheumatoid arthritis, concluded that "Amgen has leveraged its patent and lifecycle management strategies to prevent competitors from introducing lower-priced biosimilar versions of Enbrel."385

Debate

Because later-filed patents often claim aspects of a drug other than its active ingredient, these patents are sometimes called "secondary" patents.386 Critics of evergreening maintain that, by obtaining secondary patents on minor improvements or ancillary aspects of a pharmaceutical product, manufacturers effectively extend patent protection beyond the 20-year term set by Congress. In doing so, according to these critics, secondary patents unfairly shield pharmaceutical products from generic or biosimilar competition, thereby resulting in higher drug prices.387 In the view of evergreening critics, moreover, many of these secondary patents are of questionable validity.388 While secondary patents tend to be challenged more frequently by generics and more successfully than patents covering a pharmaceutical's active ingredient,389 the combination of secondary patents and a strong primary patent creates a barrier to generic entry because a generic manufacturer may delay or decline entry when faced with the prospect of defeating both patents.390 In 2019, the cost of litigating a Hatch-Waxman lawsuit was estimated to be around $5 million in cases involving over $25 million in risk.391 Commentators have suggested that these costs can be compounded when there are several patents at issue, even if some of those patents are relatively weaker.392 Thus, critics of evergreening argue that the costs of invalidating even comparatively weak patents strengthen the branded product's position in the market and can lengthen its effective period of exclusivity.393

Defenders contend that there is nothing inherently suspect about secondary patents, which must meet the same requirements for patentability and pass through the same examination procedures as any other patent.394 Those requirements bar secondary patents on any obvious variation of the primary patent or on another product or invention already available to the public.395 "[I]t is often the case," defenders contend, "that the value of a follow-on patent is comparable to, or might even exceed, that of a primary patent."396 One example arguably supporting this view is the drug Evista (raloxifine). Evista was "initially studied as a potential treatment for breast cancer" but, in 1997, FDA approved the drug for the prevention of osteoporosis.397 At that time, there were a few years left on Evista's initial patent, which was filed in 1983.398 One commentator has argued that if the brand could not patent the new use of the drug (i.e., for prevention of osteoporosis), insufficient incentives would have existed to make the investment in R&D necessary to bring the drug to market for the new use.399 Thus, critics of the notion of "evergreening" argue the term is imprecise and unfairly pejorative, creating an inaccurate impression that secondary pharmaceutical patents somewhat exploit the patent system.400

Defenders also argue that the ability to receive a patent on a later-developed drug formulation provides a significant incentive to improve on or address problems with the original formulation. For example, the original formulation of Lumigan, which is used to treat glaucoma, could cause sufficiently severe red eye that patients would discontinue its use.401 Researchers subsequently developed an improved formulation with significantly decreased risk of this side effect.402 Defenders of secondary patents contend that without the possibility of patent protection for improvements, there would have been little incentive to perform this sort of research due to the significant costs involved.403

Secondary patents are also defended as necessary to recoup development costs. One study found that even though the patent term can last as much as twenty years, delays in PTO and FDA approval decrease the nominal Orange Book patent term to 15.9 years on average, and generic competition can result in an effective market exclusivity of 12.2 years.404 This effective market exclusivity is less than the sixteen years that another commentator suggests is necessary to recoup the brand's costs for research, development, and clinical testing.405 Moreover, as secondary patents tend to be improvements to primary patents, they are typically narrower than those primary patents.406 Thus, brands argue that when the primary patent expires, any other company—including a generic—may enter the market and produce the invention covered by that primary patent, assuming the generic can design around any unexpired secondary patents.407 Doctors and patients can then decide whether the benefit conferred by a product covered by a secondary patent is worth the increased cost over the generic version of the product formerly covered by the primary patent.408

Defenders also note that congressional action has decreased the cost of challenging patents, potentially reducing the effect of later-filed secondary patents. After Congress enacted the AIA in 2011, generic and biosimilar manufacturers can use PTAB processes such as IPR,409 which was intended to "provid[e] a more efficient system for challenging patents that should not have issued; and reduc[e] unwarranted litigation costs."410 Generally, any person who is not a patent's owner may file a petition for IPR beginning nine months after the patent issues.411 The PTO then decides whether to initiate review of the patent.412 If review is initiated, then the patent challenger must prove that the patent is invalid by a preponderance of the evidence413—a lower requirement than the clear-and-convincing-evidence standard used when challenging the patent in court.414 The statute requires that the PTO's final decision be issued not more than one year after the decision to institute review.415 The median cost for litigating an IPR to that final decision is $324,000.416 Thus, IPR provides a faster and less expensive method to challenge issued patents, as compared to litigating patent validity in the courts.

Current Law

No statute specifically forbids evergreening, however the term is defined. Instead, substantive patent law, particularly the law of obviousness, provides limits on whether the PTO may grant later-filed patents. Specifically, a patent may not be granted if "the differences between the claimed invention and the prior art are such that the claimed invention as a whole would have been obvious" before the patent application was filed.417 The Supreme Court has not articulated a specific test for whether an invention would have been obvious, instead preferring a flexible approach that takes the facts and circumstances of the state of the art into account.418 The Court has identified, however, some situations in which an invention likely would have been obvious.419 For example, if the invention involves "the simple substitution of one known element for another or the mere application of a known technique to a piece of prior art ready for the improvement," the invention likely would have been obvious.420 At bottom, if the invention is "a predictable variation" of what came before, then the law of obviousness "likely bars its patentability."421

Other doctrines also affect the viability of later-filed patents. Because the patent statute limits a person to "a patent" for a new invention,422 a single patentee may not obtain a later patent that covers the exact same invention as an earlier patent.423 This doctrine is referred to as "statutory double patenting" because it derives from the patent statute and prevents patenting of the same invention twice by the same inventor.424 The courts have extended double patenting to bar an inventor from patenting obvious variations of his earlier patents as well.425 This second form of double patenting, referred to as "obviousness-type double patenting" (OTDP), prohibits a later patent that is not "patentability distinct" from an earlier commonly owned patent.426 In other words, the doctrine bars a patent owner from receiving a patent on an obvious variation of one of its earlier-filed patents.427 A patentee may overcome an OTDP issue, however, by using a "terminal disclaimer"—that is, by disclaiming any portion of the later patent's term after the expiration of the earlier patent.428

Following consultation with FDA,429 the PTO announced in 2022 that it may "[r]evisit obvious-type double patenting practice" in part because of concerns that the use terminal disclaimers may contribute to evergreening and/or patent thickets that could unduly "delay[] generic and biosimilar entry."430 PTO sought public comments on terminal disclaimers and OTDP (among other issues) in 2022 and 2023, including whether it should eliminate terminal disclaimers or limit or change OTDP practice.431

"Product Hopping"

Definition

Critics of current pharmaceutical patenting practices have observed that patent evergreening can be used in conjunction with a practice they call "product hopping."432 Product hopping is the process by which a brand, as the patents on an older branded drug are expiring, uses its current dominant market position to switch doctors, pharmacists, and consumers to a newer version of the same (or similar) drug with later-expiring patents. In other words, the brand forces a "hop" from one product to another.433 The new version of the product may be, for example, an extended release form or new dosage (e.g., moving from twice-a-day to once-a-day), a different route of administration (e.g., moving from capsules to tablets, or tablets to film strips), or a chemical change (e.g., moving to a different enantiomer).434 The switch to the new version may be accompanied by a marketing campaign or discounts and rebates to encourage doctors, insurers, and patients to switch to the new version; in some cases, production of the older version may be discontinued.435

Product hopping tends to take one of two forms: a "hard switch," where the brand removes the original product from the market, and a "soft switch," where the brand leaves the original product on the market alongside the new form.436 The case of Abbott Laboratories v. Teva Pharmaceuticals USA, Inc.437 provides one example of a hard switch. That case involved Abbott's changes to its drug TriCor, which was used to treat high cholesterol and triglycerides.438 Abbott allegedly lowered the drug's strength, switched it from a capsule to a tablet, stopped selling capsules, bought back supplies of capsules from pharmacies, and marked capsules as "obsolete" in the national drug database.439 Once generics developed equivalents for the reformulation, Abbott allegedly again lowered the drug's strength, stopped selling the original tablets, and again changed the code for the old tablets to "obsolete."440

A soft switch allegedly occurred in Schneiderman v. Actavis PLC.441 There, Actavis produced Namenda IR (IR), a twice-daily drug designed to treat Alzheimer's disease.442 As the patents on IR neared expiration and generics prepared to enter the market, Actavis introduced a once-daily version of the drug, Namenda XR (XR), and allegedly attempted to encourage doctors and patients to switch from IR to XR.443 Although the generic versions would have been substitutable for IR, the differences in dosing (10 mg in IR and 28 mg in XR) meant the generic versions would not be substitutable for the new XR product.444 Initially, both IR and XR were on the market together.445 During that time, Actavis allegedly stopped marketing IR and "spent substantial sums of money promoting XR to doctors, caregivers, patients, and pharmacists."446 Actavis also sold XR at a discount, making it much less expensive than IR, and issued rebates to ensure patients did not have to pay higher copayments for XR than IR.447 When it appeared the soft switch would only convert 30% of IR users to XR, Actavis allegedly implemented a hard switch by announcing it would discontinue IR and attempting to stop Medicare health plans from covering IR.448

Debate

Critics of product hopping deride it as an anticompetitive practice that inhibits the entry of generic and biosimilar competitors, allowing a brand to maintain its dominant market position (and higher prices) without substantial benefits for consumers.449 In particular, critics contend that by shifting product demand from the previous product to a new product, the market for a generic form of the previous version dissipates by the time the generic can enter the market.450

All fifty states have enacted drug product selection (DPS) laws, which aim to lower consumer prices by allowing, and sometimes even requiring, pharmacists to fill a prescription written for a brand-name drug with a generic version of that drug.451 Typically, pharmacists may only substitute a generic drug for a branded drug if the generic version is "AB-rated" by FDA.452 To receive an AB rating, the generic must be therapeutically equivalent to the branded drug, which means it must have the same active ingredient, form, dosage, strength, and safety and efficacy profile.453 The generic must also be bioequivalent—in other words, the rate and extent of absorption of the generic cannot significantly differ from that of the brand drug.454 Thus, if the brand's new version of a drug, for example, changes the form of the drug (e.g., capsule to tablet) or the dosage of the active ingredient (e.g., 10 mg to 12 mg) from the older version, the generic product may not receive the AB rating required to be substitutable by pharmacists.455 Even if the generic is eventually able to obtain an AB rating to allow substitution, that process may take years to achieve.456 Thus, the "hop" to a new product can prevent automatic substitution with a generic product, thereby giving the brand an additional period during which it is substantially unaffected by generic competition.

Defenders of product hopping counter that manufacturers have legitimate reasons to create new patented products and encourage doctors to prescribe the new product instead of an old product for which there is generic competition.457 One commentator has argued that patent law encourages brands to create new drugs or switch to new versions of drugs because they receive an exclusive period during which they may charge higher prices.458 That period is critical, it is argued, to recoup the estimated $2.6 billion average cost of bringing a new drug to market—compared to the $1 or $2 million its costs to bring a new generic product to market.459 Once a branded drug's patents expire, however, the brand may lose 80% to 90% of its sales to generic drug manufacturers.460 Thus, according to one commentator, brands have little incentive to keep marketing a product that is subject to generic competition; doing so would arguably transfer approximately 80% of the sales to their generic competitors. That is, even if the brand succeeds in convincing a doctor to prescribe the old product, DPS laws would allow a pharmacist to substitute a generic product instead.461 Given these economic realities, defenders argue that the brand would be effectively paying to market its competitors' products.462 On this view, product hopping aims at maximizing profits for the brand (which can be used for additional R&D) and preventing free-riding by generics, not at preventing fair competition.463

Commentators also respond that generic manufacturers could reduce the impact of product hopping by marketing their own products.464 In that view, generic manufacturers choose to rely on DPS laws for sales.465 Instead, one commentator argues, the generic companies could advertise and promote their own products in the same way that brand manufacturers do.466 In any event, patients and doctors can arguably choose to use the generic version of the old product if the brand's new product is not worth the cost.467

Current Law

There is no existing statute specifically defining or prohibiting product hopping. The practices described above have been challenged under the antitrust laws as anticompetitive attempts to maintain a monopoly in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act.468 The Schneiderman case provides one example. There, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit held that the soft switch, described above, was not sufficiently anticompetitive to violate Section 2.469 Specifically, the court determined that as long as Actavis continued to sell both XR and IR, with generic IR drugs on the market, "patients and doctors could evaluate the products and their generics on the merits in furtherance of competitive objectives."470 The Second Circuit further held that once Actavis implemented a hard switch by withdrawing IR from the market, it "crosse[d] the line from persuasion to coercion" and therefore violated Section 2.471 The court next determined that Actavis's purported procompetitive justifications for the hard switch were pretextual because the hard switch was an attempt to impede generic competition472 and, in any event, the procompetitive benefits were outweighed by anticompetitive harms.473 Accordingly, the court affirmed the district court's grant of an injunction requiring Actavis to make IR "available on the same terms and conditions" as before the hard switch.474

"Patent Thickets"

Definition

Critics have argued that some pharmaceutical manufacturers develop "patent thickets" to protect their products. This term is used in two slightly different ways, both relating to products covered by a high number of patents. First, a patent thicket may describe a situation in which multiple parties have overlapping patent rights on one product, such that a "potential manufacturer must negotiate licenses with each patent owner in order to bring a product to market without infringing."475 Patent thickets, in this sense, raise concerns about inefficient exploitation of a technology because the multiplicity of patent owners increases transaction costs and creates coordination challenges.476

Second, the term may be used in a different sense to describe one incumbent manufacturer's practice of amassing a large number of patents relating to a single product, with the intent of intimidating competitors from entering the market, or making it too costly and risky to do so.477 It is this second usage that is usually intended when critics refer to the patent "thickets" protecting pharmaceutical products.

Debate

Commentators have observed that single products are frequently protected by multiple patents.478 For example, it has been estimated that a single smartphone may be protected by as many as 250,000 patents.479 Even the individual technologies in the phone may be covered by many patents. For example, Bluetooth 3.0 incorporates "contributions of more than 30,000 patent holders," and more than 800 patent holders contributed to the micro-SD removable memory storage card.480 Unlike pharmaceuticals, the patents on products like semiconductors or smartphones are typically not all owned by the same entity, and thus are examples of the first type of patent thicket (i.e., one in which multiple parties have overlapping patent rights on a product). Commentators contend that patent thickets on such technologies generally do not confer the same market power as a patent portfolio on a new pharmaceutical owned by a single drug manufacturer.481

In the pharmaceutical context, patent thicket concerns often focus on biologics. At least in part, this may occur because biologics are derived from living cells or other biological material.482 Naturally occurring source material is not itself eligible for patenting under Section 101 of the Patent Act,483 but methods for transforming source material into a biological product generally are patentable.484 In addition, biologics that are genetically modified or otherwise altered by man into a non-naturally occurring form are patent-eligible.485 Manufacturing a pharmaceutical using living cells is often complicated, offering more opportunities for patenting relative to chemically synthesizing small-molecule drugs.486 As changes are implemented to either the biologic product or its manufacturing process throughout the original patent term, those changes can be claimed as inventions and used to extend the effective patent protection.487 For example, a company producing a biologic could attempt to patent the use of a different medium for cell growth or an adjustment to the dosing.488

The patent portfolio that covers Humira, pharmaceutical manufacturer AbbVie's flagship biologic—a monoclonal antibody used to treat arthritis and other conditions—has been characterized as an example of the second type of patent thicket.489 By one measure, AbbVie obtained at least 132 patents relating to this product.490 Although the primary patent on Humira expired in 2016, critics argue that these dozens of secondary patents created a thicket of protection that prevented would-be biosimilar makers from entering the market.491 For example, the Biosimilars Council alleges that AbbVie filed 75 patents relating to Humira in the three years before biosimilar competition could begin, extending nominal patent protection through 2034.492

In August 2017, just before biosimilar manufacturer Boehringer received FDA approval to launch its Humira biosimilar in the United States, AbbVie filed a lawsuit alleging that the biosimilar would infringe 74 of AbbVie's patents.493 Boehringer settled the lawsuit two years later, in 2019, citing "the inherent unpredictability of litigation, [and] the substantial costs of what would have been a long and complicated legal process and ongoing distraction to our business."494 AbbVie has similarly settled litigation with other potential manufacturers of Humira biosimilars.495 Pursuant to these settlements, biosimilars for Humira entered the market in 2023, seven years after the primary Humira patent expired but more than 10 years before the expiration of some of its later secondary patents.496

The alleged patent thicket surrounding Humira has been the subject of litigation, including under the antitrust laws. In March 2019, a welfare fund filed an antitrust suit against AbbVie alleging that its patent thicket approach unreasonably restrained competition in violation of Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act.497 The trial judge dismissed the complaint without prejudice in June 2020, determining that "AbbVie has exploited advantages conferred on it through lawful practices and to the extent this has kept prices high for Humira, existing antitrust doctrine does not prohibit it."498 On appeal, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit affirmed, agreeing with the district court that acquiring large numbers of patents does not itself represent an antitrust violation.499 In the view of the Seventh Circuit, if "AbbVie made 132 inventions," there is no reason why "it [can't] hold 132 patents"; if those patents are invalid, they can be challenged in court or at the PTAB.500

Defenders of this patenting practice raise arguments that are similar to those supporting evergreening: secondary patents, even numerous ones, represent innovations the patent laws were designed to encourage, and that each patent has passed through the rigorous examination process and been determined to be novel and nonobvious.501 For example, AbbVie has stated that Humira "represents true innovation in the field of biologics,"502 warranting protection through all the various patents.503 Other experts note that "[t]here's nothing unusual about the multilayered way AbbVie has sought to patent and protect Humira," and that patent thickets simply "tak[e] advantage of existing law."504 Accordingly, companies with patents relating to numerous aspects of their products likely view each patent as protecting significant patentable innovations of the sort the patent system is designed to protect.505

Experts note that creating a biologic like Humira "isn't easy work."506 Scientists must genetically engineer a cell line to secrete large amounts of the biologic, purify the results, and modify dosages for different diseases, among other "incremental tweaks."507 Each of those steps in the process brings challenges that may require innovative solutions, and those solutions may be the subject of patents.508 As AbbVie's CEO noted, the Humira "patent portfolio evolved as [AbbVie] discovered and learned new things about Humira."509 Thus, defenders view alleged patent "thickets" as an ordinary and legitimate use of the patent system to protect the different aspects of their innovations.

Current Law

No statute specifically forbids patent thickets. As discussed above, the Seventh Circuit's opinion in the Humira case held that nothing in the Patent Act or the Sherman Act precluded AbbVie from obtaining 132 patents on its product, regardless of whether one characterizes that patent portfolio as a "thicket."510

Like evergreening, substantive patent law (including the nonobviousness requirement and the prohibition on double patenting) provides some of the primary restrictions on obtaining overlapping patents. In other words, the ability to receive secondary patents is limited by the rule that new patents cannot be an obvious variation on the prior art or on the patentee's own prior patents.511 On the other hand, OTDP restrictions may have less impact on patent thickets than on evergreening due to the availability of terminal disclaimers. As explained above, a patentee may overcome OTDP issues by disclaiming any portion of the later patent's term after the earlier patent expires.512 Because the alleged goal of evergreening is to extend the exclusivity period for as long as possible, there is little incentive to file a terminal disclaimer. By contrast, the purported goal of a patent thicket is to accumulate a large number of patents protecting a single product, a goal that would be unaffected by terminal disclaimers. Thus, restrictions on OTDP may not prevent patent thickets as effectively as they might limit evergreening.

"Pay-for-Delay" or "Reverse Payment" Settlements

Definition

As described above, patent litigation can result when generic drug and biosimilar manufacturers challenge the validity of brand-name companies' patents and/or their applicability to follow-on products.513 As with much litigation, these cases often end through settlement agreements.

Some brand-name companies resolve such litigation through settlement agreements with generic manufacturers whereby the brand-name company pays the generic manufacturer or provides other compensation in return for the generic manufacturer agreeing to delay market entry.514 This practice is often referred to as "reverse payment settlements" or "pay-for-delay settlements." Because these agreements terminate the litigation, the questions of patent validity and infringement remain open.515 As a result, this type of agreement allows the brand-name company to avoid the risk that its patents will be invalidated and, compared to the outcome where the patents are invalidated, delay the market entry of generic competition and effectively extend the brand-name company's exclusive right to market the listed drug.516 Meanwhile, the generic company receives compensation (in addition to avoiding further litigation costs that may have resulted in the patents being upheld) and may still be able to enter the market before the patents expire, depending on the terms of the agreement.

Pay-for-delay settlements are not limited to cash payments from the brand to the generic. In 2017, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit addressed such a settlement involving Wyeth, Inc.'s branded antidepressant drug, Effexor XR.517 In that case, the plaintiffs alleged that Wyeth and generic manufacturer Teva Pharmaceutical Industries Ltd. (Teva) reached an anticompetitive pay-for-delay settlement.518 Teva filed an ANDA for a generic version of Effexor XR, and Wyeth sued for patent infringement.519 According to the plaintiffs (a class of direct purchasers of Effexor XR), an unfavorable preliminary ruling caused Wyeth to fear that it would lose the litigation, allowing generic manufacturers to enter the Effexor XR market.520

Accordingly, Wyeth and Teva entered into a settlement in which

  • the parties agreed to vacate the unfavorable preliminary ruling;
  • Teva agreed not to enter the market with its Effexor XR generic until approximately five years after the agreement (nearly seven years before Wyeth's patents expired);
  • Wyeth agreed not to market a competing "authorized generic"521 during Teva's 180-day exclusivity period;
  • Wyeth agreed to permit Teva to sell a generic version of another product, Effexor IR, before the original patent on Effexor expired and without a Wyeth-authorized generic; and
  • Teva agreed to pay royalties to Wyeth on its sales of both generic versions of Effexor.522

Pursuant to a consent decree, Wyeth and Teva submitted the agreement to the FTC.523 The FTC did not object to the agreement.524 Notably, Wyeth did not pay money directly to Teva. Instead, Wyeth's agreement not to market an authorized generic during Teva's 180-day exclusivity period would cause Teva to reap increased sales during that period. In other words, although Wyeth did not directly pay Teva to keeps its generic product out of the market, the agreement ensured that Teva would receive compensation in other ways.

Debate

The FTC and others have alleged that pay-for-delay settlements "have significant adverse effects on competition" in violation of antitrust laws, including Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 5 of the FTC Act.525 When evaluating agreements for potential antitrust violations, courts focus on "form[ing] a judgment about the competitive significance of the [settlement] . . . 'based either (1) on the nature or character of the contracts, or (2) on surrounding circumstances giving rise to the inference or presumption that they were intended to restrain trade and enhance prices.'"526 The Supreme Court has recognized that "reverse payment settlements . . . can sometimes violate the antitrust laws,"527 and courts have allowed antitrust litigation challenging certain reverse payment settlements to proceed under existing law.528

Defenders of such agreements contend there are significant benefits from pay-for-delay settlements. For example, AbbVie has settled suits with each of the companies that sought to introduce biosimilars to Humira.529 Even while accusing AbbVie of "patent abuses" relating to Humira, the Biosimilars Council has touted using settlements between brands and biosimilars to resolve patent "thicket" disputes.530 The Council contends that the Humira settlements are pro-consumer because, although biosimilar market entry will be delayed until seven years after the primary patent on Humira has expired, entry will still occur before several of the secondary patents covering Humira will expire.531 As the Supreme Court has recognized, pay-for-delay settlements may provide significant procompetitive benefits, and whether a particular settlement is procompetitive or anticompetitive will depend on a number of factors that vary from case to case.532

Pay-for-delay settlements may now be uncommon. A 2020 FTC report found that in Fiscal Year 2017, brand and generic pharmaceutical manufacturers settled 226 patent disputes.533 According to that report, 3 of those 226 settlements restricted generic entry and provided compensation beyond the repayment of legal fees.534

Current Law

In Actavis v. FTC, the Supreme Court held that the rule of reason is the appropriate level of analysis in challenges to pay-for-delay agreements.535 Although the Court recognized the potential for such agreements to have anticompetitive effects, it acknowledged that "offsetting or redeeming virtues are sometimes present."536 Such justifications might include "traditional settlement considerations, such as avoided litigation costs or fair value for services."537 Accordingly, the FTC (or other plaintiffs) has to prove the anticompetitive effects of a particular agreement before the burden shifts to the defendant.538

The Third Circuit case involving the Wyeth-Teva agreement provides an example of the current analysis. Although the FTC did not object to the agreement, purchasers of Effexor XR filed a class action lawsuit against Wyeth and Teva alleging, inter alia, that the settlement agreement was an unlawful restraint of trade under Section 1 of the Sherman Act.539 The Third Circuit concluded that the plaintiffs plausibly alleged an anticompetitive pay-for-delay settlement.540 The court determined that Wyeth's agreement not to manufacture a competing generic product during Teva's 180-day exclusivity period was an adequate allegation of a sufficiently large payment because it ensured Teva would be the only generic product on the market, and thus Teva would receive all generic Effexor XR sales during that period.541 The court concluded that the payment could not be justified as a simple effort to avoid the costs of litigation.542 Accordingly, the court determined that the plaintiffs adequately alleged that the agreement between Wyeth and Teva was anticompetitive under the Actavis standard.543

Combinations of Practices

Although this report describes various patenting practices in isolation, patent holders can also use them concurrently. For example, product hopping can be combined with pay-for-delay settlements to delay generic entry while a brand switches the market to a new product. A manufacturer considering product hopping will often be more successful in preventing competition from the generic if it can convert the market to the new product before the generic enters the market.544 In one case, the brand estimated that it would sell ten times more tablets if it could switch doctors to the new product before the generic entered the market.545

One example of a drug manufacturer allegedly combining product hopping and pay-for-delay settlements to prevent competition for its product involves Cephalon, maker of the branded sleep-disorder medication Provigil.546 Between its secondary patent and a period of regulatory exclusivity, nominal protection of Provigil expired in April 2015.547 Due to the secondary patent's narrowness, however, the generic companies planned to enter the market with noninfringing products in 2006.548 Cephalon estimated that, once the generic versions entered the market, there would be a 75% to 90% price reduction in Provigil, reducing revenues by more than $400 million in the first year alone.549 In 2006, Cephalon attempted to move the market to a new product, Nuvigil, which was patent-protected until 2023.550 FDA had not yet approved Nuvigil in late 2005 when Cephalon settled its patent lawsuits with the generics, paying them more than $200 million to delay market entry until 2012.551

Although Cephalon argued its settlement would allow generic versions of Provigil to enter the market three years before the expiration of the Provigil secondary patent in 2015, following the settlement, Cephalon increased the price of Provigil and stopped marketing it.552 At the same time, Cephalon promoted Nuvigil both through its sales force and by discounting its price.553 Through the pay-for-delay settlement, Cephalon had until 2012 to switch the market to Nuvigil rather than begin competing against the generics with Provigil in 2006. Thus, Cephalon arguably combined product hopping with pay-for-delay settlements to prolong its period of exclusivity.

Conclusion

IP rights play an important role in encouraging pharmaceutical innovation and development of new drugs and biologics. They may also contribute to the perceived high prices of pharmaceuticals in the United States. The effects that regulatory exclusivities, patents, and pharmaceutical patenting practices have on drug prices depend on a complex interplay between patent law, FDA law, the Hatch-Waxman Act, the BPCIA, and antitrust law. The fundamental issue for Congress in this area is whether current law effectively balances innovation and competition in the pharmaceutical market.

Footnotes

1.

See, e.g., The Need to Make Insulin Affordable for All Americans: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Health, Educ., Labor & Pensions, 118th Cong. (2023); Lower Drug Costs Now: Expanding Access to Affordable Health Care: Hearing Before the H. Subcomm. on Health, Employment, Labor and Pensions of the H. Comm. on Educ. & Labor, 117th Cong. (2021); Why Does the US Pay the Highest Prices in the World for Prescription Drugs?: Hearing Before the S. Comm. On Health, Educ., Labor & Pensions, 117th Cong. (2021); Unsustainable Drug Prices: Testimony from the CEOs (Parts I and II): Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Oversight & Reform, 116th Cong. (2020); Intellectual Property and the Price of Prescription Drugs: Balancing Innovation and Competition: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 116th Cong. (2019); Drug Pricing in America: A Prescription for Change (Parts I–III): Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Fin., 116th Cong. (2019); The Cost of Rising Prescription Drug Prices, Hearing Before the H. Ways & Means Comm., 116th Cong. (2019); Examining the Actions of Drug Companies in Raising Prescription Drug Prices: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Oversight & Reform, 116th Cong. (2019).

Both the Biden and Trump administrations released plans and used executive authorities to plans to address rising drug prices. See generally U.S. Dep't of Health & Human Servs., Comprehensive Plan for Addressing High Drug Prices: A Report in Reponses to the Executive Order on Competition in the American Economy (2021), https://aspe.hhs.gov/sites/default/files/2021-09/Drug_Pricing_Plan_9-9-2021.pdf; U.S. Dep't of Health & Human Servs., American Patients First: The Trump Administration Blueprint to Lower Drug Prices and Reduce Out-of-Pocket Costs (2018), https://www.hhs.gov/sites/default/files/AmericanPatientsFirst.pdf.

2.

For an examination of some of these proposals, see CRS Report R46741, Drug Pricing and Intellectual Property: The Legislative Landscape for the 117th Congress, by Kevin J. Hickey, Kevin T. Richards, and Erin H. Ward (2021).

3.

Dep't of Health & Human Servs., Observations on Trends in Prescription Drug Spending 1 (Mar. 8, 2016), https://aspe.hhs.gov/sites/default/files/pdf/187586/Drugspending.pdf; see also CRS Report R44832, Frequently Asked Questions About Prescription Drug Pricing and Policy, by Suzanne M. Kirchhoff et al., at 3–7 (2021).

4.

See generally Kirchhoff et al., supra note 3, at 21–23. For studies on this issue, see for example, GAO, Prescription Drugs: U.S. Prices for Selected Brand Drugs Were Higher on Average than Prices in Australia, Canada, and France (2021), https://www.gao.gov/assets/gao-21-282.pdf (finding U.S. prices for 20 brand-name prescription drugs were two to four times higher than selected comparison countries); Andrew WQ. Mulcahy et al., International Prescription Drug Price Comparisons, Rand Corp. (2021), https://www.rand.org/pubs/research_reports/RR2956.html (finding U.S. drug prices in 2018 were 2.56 times higher than 32 comparison countries); OECD, Health at a Glance 2021, at p. 237 fig. 9.2 (finding U.S. 2019 per capita expenditures on pharmaceuticals was the highest among all countries studied and more than twice the OECD average).

5.

See generally Kirchhoff et al., supra note 3, at 3–13; Joseph Antos & James C. Capretta, Prescription Drug Pricing: An Overview of the Legal, Regulatory and Market Environment, Am. Enter. Inst. 4–12 (2018), https://www.aei.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/07/Prescription-Drug-Pricing.pdf; Aaron S. Kesselheim et al., The High Cost of Prescription Drugs in the United States: Origins and Prospects for Reform, 316 JAMA: J. Am. Med. Ass'n 858, 860–63 (2016).

6.

See, e.g., William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law 313 (2003) (citing data that new drug manufacturers are unusually "avid in seeking patent protection"); Emily Michiko Morris, The Myth of Generic Pharmaceutical Competition under the Hatch-Waxman Act, 22 Fordham Intell. Prop. Media & Ent. L.J. 245, 252 (2012) ("[P]harmaceuticals are also widely recognized as one of the industries most dependent on patent protection to recoup its enormous research, development, regulatory, and post-marketing costs."); Adi Gillat, Compulsory Licensing to Regulated Licensing: Effects on the Conflict Between Innovation and Access in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 58 Food & Drug L.J. 711, 722 (reviewing data "supporting relatively high dependency of the pharmaceutical industry on patent rights").

7.

See, e.g., Kesselheim et al., supra note 5, at 861 ("The most important factor that allows manufacturers to set high drug prices for brand-name drugs is market exclusivity, which arises from 2 forms of legal protection against competition [i.e., regulatory exclusivities and patent rights.]"); Generic Competition and Drug Prices, Food & Drug Admin. (Sept. 12, 2022), https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/center-drug-evaluation-and-research-cder/generic-competition-and-drug-prices (finding association between generic competition and lower drug prices).

8.

See Generic Competition and Drug Prices, supra note 7 (showing sharp price decreases associated with the number of generic producers of a drug).

9.

See, e.g., Robin Feldman & Evan Frondorf, Drug Wars: A New Generation of Generic Pharmaceutical Delay, 53 Harv. J. on Legis. 499, 556–61 (2016) (urging "comprehensive overhaul" of pharmaceutical patent laws to curtail strategies used by pharmaceutical companies to avoid competition and maintain monopoly pricing); Kesselheim et al., supra note 5, at 864 (proposing limits on secondary patents and increased policing of pay-for-delay patent settlements as possible means to curtail high drug prices).

10.

See Henry G. Grabowski et al., The Roles of Patents and Research and Development Incentives in Biopharmaceutical Innovation, 34 Health Affs. 302, 302 (2015) ("Patents and other forms of intellectual property protection are generally thought to play essential roles in encouraging innovation in biopharmaceuticals.").

11.

See infra notes 3443 (discussing economic rationale for IP and the costs and benefits that it may impose on the public).

12.

See infra "Regulatory Exclusivities."

13.

Under the FD&C Act, a "drug" means, among other things, an article that is "intended for use in the diagnosis, cure, mitigation, treatment, or prevention of disease in man or other animals." 21 U.S.C. § 321(g)(1).

14.

Under the PHSA, a "biological product" or "biologic" is a medical product derived from natural sources (human, animal, microorganism) and applicable to the prevention, treatment, or cure of disease. 42 U.S.C. § 262(i)(1).

15.

See infra "FDA Approval and Licensure of Pharmaceutical Products."

16.

Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (1984) (codified as amended in relevant part at 21 U.S.C. § 355 and 35 U.S.C. §§ 156, 271(e)).

17.

Pub. L. No. 111-148, tit. VII, 124 Stat. 199, 804–21 (2010) (codified as amended in relevant part at 42 U.S.C. § 262 and 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)).

18.

See infra "FDA Approval and Licensure of Pharmaceutical Products."

19.

See infra "Securing and Enforcing Patent Protections for Pharmaceuticals."

20.

See infra "Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs and Biosimilars."

21.

See infra "Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices."

22.

Cf. Intellectual Property, Black's Law Dictionary (10th ed. 2014) ("A category of intangible rights protecting commercially valuable products of the human intellect.").

23.

See generally CRS In Focus IF10986, Intellectual Property Law: A Brief Introduction, by Kevin J. Hickey (2022).

24.

See id.

25.

Although patents and regulatory exclusivities are the most important forms of IP rights for pharmaceuticals, drugs and biologics may be subject to other varieties of IP. For example, the brand name of a new drug is typically trademarked, which prevents other manufacturers from using the same (or a similar) name in a way that would confuse consumers about the source of goods or services. See 15 U.S.C. § 1114(1); see generally CRS In Focus IF12456, An Introduction to Trademark Law in the United States, by Christopher T. Zirpoli (2023).

26.

Although not a traditional form of IP such as a copyright or patent, regulatory exclusivities share many of the features of traditional IP rights and thus are often characterized as a form of IP. See, e.g., John R. Thomas, The End of "Patent Medicines"? Thoughts on the Rise of Regulatory Exclusivities, 70 Food & Drug L.J. 39, 43 (2015) (describing regulatory exclusivities as "FDA-administered intellectual property rights"); Rebecca S. Eisenberg, The Role of the FDA in Innovation Policy, 13 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 345, 359 (2007) (describing FDA regulatory exclusivities as "pseudo-patents"). Regulatory exclusivities are analogous to patent rights because they confer a limited monopoly on the exclusivity holder to provide an incentive for drug manufacturers to undertake the investments necessary to complete the FDA regulatory process. See Maxwell R. Morgan, Regulation of Innovation under Follow-on Biologics Legislation: FDA Exclusivity As an Efficient Incentive Mechanism, 11 Colum. Sci. & Tech. L. Rev. 93, 98 (2010) ("Like patent law, an FDA-administered exclusivity period can effectively confer a monopoly on a market entrant, and thereby act as an incentive mechanism for firms to invest in the generation and clinical development of new medicines, and also in commercializing them.").

27.

In general, a patent may be granted on any "new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof." 35 U.S.C. § 101. However, "laws of nature, natural phenomena, and abstract ideas are not patentable." Alice Corp. v. CLS Bank Int'l, 573 U.S. 208, 216 (2014) (quoting Ass'n for Molecular Pathology v. Myriad Genetics, Inc., 569 U.S. 576, 589 (2013)); see generally CRS Report R45918, Patent-Eligible Subject Matter Reform: Background and Issues for Congress, by Kevin J. Hickey (2022).

28.

See 35 U.S.C. §§ 101-103, 131. Patent applications must also conform to a number of requirements related to the sufficiency of the technical disclosure in the patent itself. Id. § 112; see generally CRS Report R46525, Patent Law: A Handbook for Congress, coordinated by Kevin J. Hickey (2020), at 8–17 (reviewing patentability requirements).

29.

35 U.S.C. §§ 154(a)(2), 271(a).

30.

See infra "FDA Approval and Licensure of Pharmaceutical Products."

31.

See infra "Regulatory Exclusivities"; see generally CRS In Focus IF11217, Drug Pricing and the Law: Regulatory Exclusivities, by Erin H. Ward (2019).

32.

Ward, supra note 31.

33.

Id.

34.

An exception is trademark law, which is usually justified by a different rationale: protecting consumers from confusion and lowering product search costs by preventing businesses from misrepresenting the source of goods or services. See Qualitex Co. v. Jacobson Prods. Co., 514 U.S. 159, 163–64 (1995). Many alternative rationales for IP rights exist in addition to the incentives-for-creation theory. See, e.g., Justin Hughes, The Philosophy of Intellectual Property, 77 Geo. L.J. 287, 296–314 (1988) (articulating justification for intellectual property as natural right deriving from the author's labor); id. at 330–39 (articulating justification for intellectual property as rooted in notions of personhood); Colleen V. Chien, Contextualizing Patent Disclosure, 69 Vand. L. Rev. 1849, 1850–51 (2016) (overviewing justification for patent system as an incentive to encourage innovators to disclose technical information to public).

35.

See Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 429 (1984) ("[Copyrights and patents are] intended to motivate the creative activity of authors and inventors by the provision of a special reward, and to allow the public access to the products of their genius after the limited period of exclusive control has expired."); Twentieth Century Music Corp. v. Aiken, 422 U.S. 151, 156 (1975) ("The immediate effect of our copyright law is to secure a fair return for an 'author's' creative labor. But the ultimate aim is, by this incentive, to stimulate artistic creativity for the general public good.").

36.

See Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U.S. 470, 480 (1974) ("The patent laws promote [the progress of the useful arts] by offering a right of exclusion for a limited period as an incentive to inventors to risk the often enormous costs in terms of time, research, and development.").

37.

See Grabowski et al., supra note 10, at 302 ("[T]he process of developing a new drug and bringing it to market is long, costly, and risky, and the costs of imitation are low. After a new drug has been approved and is being marketed, its patents protect it from competition from chemically identical entrants (or entrants infringing on other patents) for a period of time."); Landes & Posner, supra note 6, at 24 ("If the fixed costs of intellectual property—the costs incurred before a single sale is made—are very high and . . . the costs of duplication are slight, then in the absence of intellectual property rights either the intellectual property will not be created or the government will have to finance it . . . ."); id. at 317 ("In the case of new drugs . . . the fixed costs of research and development are very high, in part because of stringent regulatory requirements, but the marginal costs [of imitators] are very low.").

38.

Mazer v. Stein, 347 U.S. 201, 219 (1954).

39.

See Sony, 464 U.S. at 429 ("[D]efining the scope of [patents and copyrights] involves a difficult balance between the interests of authors and inventors in the control and exploitation of their writings and discoveries on the one hand, and society's competing interest in the free flow of ideas, information, and commerce on the other hand. . . . "); Mark A. Lemley, Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding, 83 Tex. L. Rev. 1031, 1031 (2005) ("[Traditionally,] the proper goal of intellectual property law is to give as little protection as possible consistent with encouraging innovation.").

40.

See infra notes 110112 and accompanying text.

41.

See, e.g., Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co., 535 U.S. 722, 730 (2002) (characterizing patents as a "temporary monopoly"); Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, Inc., 489 U.S. 141, 147 (1989) (characterizing patents as a "limited monopoly"); Sony, 464 U.S. at 442 (characterizing copyright as a "statutory monopoly"). Notably, this usage of "monopoly" is somewhat imprecise, because the exclusive rights provided by IP law do not necessarily confer monopolistic market power in the economic sense; for example, there may be noninfringing substitutes for a patented good in the relevant market. See Landes & Posner, supra note 6, at 22 ("[IP] protection creates a monopoly, in the literal sense in which a person has a monopoly in the house he owns but [only] occasionally in a meaningful economic sense as well because there may be no good substitutes for a particular intellectual work.").

42.

35 U.S.C. §§ 154, 271.

43.

See Landes & Posner, supra note 6, at 299–300; FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136, 147 (2013) ("[Patent rights] may permit the patent owner to charge a higher-than-competitive price for the patented product.").

44.

See infra "Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices."

45.

See, e.g. Press Release, Office of Sen. Dick Durbin, Durbin, Cassidy Introduce REMEDY Act To Lower Drug Prices By Curbing Patent Manipulation, Promoting Generic Competition (Apr. 11, 2019), https://www.durbin.senate.gov/newsroom/press-releases/durbin-cassidy-introduce-remedy-act-to-lower-drug-prices-by-curbing-patent-manipulation-promoting-generic-competition ("Americans are facing skyrocketing prescription drug costs in part because brand-name pharma manufacturers have gamed the patent system to extend their monopolies and avoid competition from lower-cost generic drugs.") (quoting Sen. Durbin); Press Release, Office of Sen. John Cornyn, Cornyn, Blumenthal Introduce Bill to Prevent Drug Companies from Abusing Patent System (May 9, 2019) ("Drug companies have taken advantage of the patent system to maintain their monopoly on certain drugs and prevent generics from coming to market.") (quoting Sen. Cornyn).

46.

See, e.g., infra notes 394416 and accompanying text.

47.

See generally Hickey et al., supra note 2.

48.

See, e.g., Feldman & Frondorf, supra note 9, at 556–61 (urging "comprehensive overhaul" of pharmaceutical patent laws to curtail strategies pharmaceutical companies allegedly use to avoid competition and maintain monopoly pricing); Kesselheim et al., supra note 5, at 864 (proposing limits on secondary patents and increased policing of pay-for-delay patent settlements as possible means to curtail high drug prices).

49.

See infra "Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices."

50.

See generally Wallace F. Janssen, The Story of the Laws Behind the Labels, Food & Drug Admin. (1981), https://www.fda.gov/downloads/aboutfda/history/forgshistory/evolvingpowers/ucm593437.pdf.

51.

21 U.S.C. § 355(a); 42 U.S.C. § 262(a)(1).

52.

See, e.g., King Drug Co. of Florence, Inc. v. Smithkline Beecham Corp., 791 F.3d 388, 394 (3d Cir. 2015) ("Congress attempted to balance the goal of 'mak[ing] available more low cost generic drugs, H.R. Rep. No. 98-857, pt. 1, at 14–15 (1984), reprinted in 1984 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2647, 2647–48, with the value of patent monopolies in incentivizing beneficial pharmaceutical advancement, see H.R. Rep. No. 98-857, pt. 2, at 30 (1984), reprinted in 1984 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2686, 2714."); Yaniv Heled, Patents v. Statutory Exclusivities in Biological PharmaceuticalsDo We Really Need Both?, 18 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 419, 427–30, 434–36 (2012).

53.

See infra "Regulatory Exclusivities."

54.

See generally 21 U.S.C. § 355; 42 U.S.C. § 262.

55.

21 U.S.C. § 321(g).

56.

Id. § 321(p).

57.

Id. § 355(a).

58.

FTC v. Actavis, 570 U.S. 136, 142 (2013).

59.

"Safety" in the FDA context is measured by the number and seriousness of adverse events and reactions in persons exposed to the drug. See, e.g., 21 C.F.R. § 312.32 (2023).

60.

"Efficacy" refers to whether the drug performs better than a placebo under controlled conditions. See generally Amit Singal, Peter Higgins & Akbar Waljee, A Primer on Effectiveness and Efficacy Trials, 5(1) J. Clinical & Translational Gastroenterology e45 (2014), https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3912314/. Effectiveness examines how the drug performs under real-world conditions where it may not be prescribed or taken as intended or may interact with other drugs or health conditions. Id.

61.

21 C.F.R. § 314.50(d)(5).

62.

21 U.S.C. §355(i); 21 C.F.R. § 312.21. As amended by the Consolidated Appropriations Act, 2023, the FD&C Act provides that nonclinical tests used to support evidence of a drug's safety or effectiveness may include any in vitro, in silico, or in chemico test, or a nonhuman in vivo test, before or during the clinical trial phase, including cell-based assays, organ chips and microphysiological systems, computer modeling, other nonhuman or human biology-based test methods, and animal tests. 21 U.S.C. § 355(z).

63.

21 C.F.R. § 312.20.

64.

Id. § 312.23.

65.

Id. §§ 312.40, 312.42.

66.

Id. § 312.21.

67.

Id. § 312.21(a).

68.

Id.

69.

Id. § 312.21(b)–(c).

70.

Id.

71.

Id.

72.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b). The FD&C Act provides for two types of NDAs in section 505(b), depending on whether the application includes only studies to which the company has a right of reference (under 505(b)(1)) or includes studies to which the company does not have a right of reference (e.g., published literature or FDA's finding of safety and efficacy for a related approved drug) (a so-called "paper NDA" under 505(b)(2)). Id.; see also U.S. Food & Drug Admin., DRAFT Guidance for Industry: Applications Covered by Section 505(b)(2) (1999), https://www.fda.gov/downloads/Drugs/Guidances/ucm079345.pdf.

73.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b).

74.

21 U.S.C. § 355(d).

75.

Id.

76.

U.S. Food & Drug Admin., Demonstrating Substantial Evidence of Effectiveness for Human Drug and Biological Products: Draft Guidance for Industry 3 (Dec. 2019), https://www.fda.gov/media/133660/download.

77.

Id. Manufacturing information includes the manufacturer's name and address, manufacturing methods and process controls, and specifications to ensure a product's integrity for both the marketed drug substance and any drug components used to manufacture the drug. 21 C.F.R. § 314.50(d)(1).

78.

21 C.F.R. § 314.105.

79.

Id.

80.

Id.

81.

Id. § 314.110.

82.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b) (1982). FDA did permit applicants to rely on published studies to meet the "full reports of investigations" requirement through its Paper NDA policy. See Publication of "Paper NDA" Memorandum, 46 Fed. Reg. 27396, 27396 (May 19, 1981).

83.

Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act, Pub. L. No. 98-417, § 101, 98 Stat. 1585 (1984) (referred to as the Hatch-Waxman Act).

84.

21 C.F.R. §§ 314.92, 314.94.

85.

Actavis v. FTC, 570 U.S. 136, 142 (2013).

86.

Drugs are pharmaceutically equivalent if they have the same active ingredient(s), strength, dosage form, and route of administration. 21 C.F.R. § 314.3. Other elements that do not impact safety or effectiveness, such as the drug's inactive ingredients, may be different. Id.

87.

Bioequivalence means the drugs work the same way inside the body; that is, there is no significant difference in the rate at which and extent to which the drug's active ingredient reaches the place in the body where the drug is active, when administered at the same dose and under similar conditions. Id. § 320.1(e).

88.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A); 21 C.F.R. §§ 314.94, 320.21.

89.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(v).

90.

See infra "The Hatch-Waxman Act: Patents and Generic Drug Approval."

91.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A).

92.

42 U.S.C. § 262(i); 21 C.F.R. § 600.3.

93.

U.S. Food & Drug Admin., Biological Product Definitions, https://www.fda.gov/downloads/Drugs/DevelopmentApprovalProcess/HowDrugsareDevelopedandApproved/ApprovalApplications/TherapeuticBiologicApplications/Biosimilars/UCM581282.pdf (last visited Jan. 26, 2024)

94.

Id.

95.

Id.

96.

42 U.S.C. § 262(a)(1).

97.

21 C.F.R. § 601.2(a). An intercenter agreement between CBER and CDER governs which center reviews a particular product application and regulates the product if approved. Intercenter Agreement Between the Center for Drug Evaluation and Research and the Center for Biologics Evaluation and Research, Food & Drug Admin. (Oct. 25, 1991), https://www.fda.gov/CombinationProducts/JurisdictionalInformation/ucm121179.htm. In 2003, FDA transferred some therapeutic biological products from CBER to CDER. See Transfer of Therapeutic Biological Products to the Center for Drug Evaluation and Research, Food & Drug Admin. (June 30, 2003), https://www.fda.gov/CombinationProducts/JurisdictionalInformation/ucm136265.htm.

98.

21 C.F.R. § 601.2(a). FDA requires Medication Guides for products that "pose a serious and significant public health concern," necessitating patient labeling to inform patients of serious adverse risks and ensure safe and effective use of the product. Id. § 208.1. Generally, FDA requires Medication Guides for "prescription drug products used on an outpatient basis without direct supervision by a health professional." Id.

99.

Id. § 601.20.

100.

42 U.S.C. § 262(a)(2)(C). A product is safe when it is "relative[ly] free[] from harmful effect to the persons affected, directly or indirectly, by a product when prudently administered," accounting for the product's nature and the recipient's condition. 21 C.F.R. § 600.3(p). A pure product is "relative[ly] free[] from extraneous matter in the finished product," regardless of whether the extraneous matter is harmful. Id. § 600.3(r). Finally, the potency of the product depends on its "specific ability or capacity . . . to effect a given result," as demonstrated through "appropriate laboratory tests or by adequately controlled clinical data." Id. § 600.3(s).

101.

21 C.F.R. §§ 601.3, 601.4.

102.

Id. § 601.12.

103.

42 U.S.C. § 262(k).

104.

Id. § 262(i)(2).

105.

Id. § 262(k)(2)(A)(i)(III).

106.

Id. § 262(k)(2)(A)(i)(II) & (IV).

107.

Id. § 262(k)(2)(A)(i)(V).

108.

Id. § 262(k)(4).

109.

Id. § 262(k)(4).

110.

Id. § 262(i)(3).

111.

See, e.g., King Drug Co. of Florence, Inc. v. Smithkline Beecham Corp., 791 F.3d 388, 394 (3d Cir. 2015) ("[Through] Hatch-Waxman, Congress attempted to balance the goal of 'mak[ing] available more low cost generic drugs,' with the value of patent monopolies in incentivizing beneficial pharmaceutical advancement[.]" (internal citations omitted)); Heled, supra note 52. For a comparison of regulatory exclusivities and patent exclusivities, see infra Table 2.

112.

Heled, supra note 52, at 427–30, 440.

113.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii), (iv); 42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(6); see also Actavis v. FTC, 570 U.S. 136, 143–44 (2013); Heled, supra note 52, at 428–29.

114.

There is no standard terminology for regulatory exclusivities. Some commentators use terms such as "data protection" and "marketing exclusivity" synonymously with "regulatory exclusivity." This report follows a second approach that ascribes distinct meanings to the terms. See generally Heled, supra note 52, at 436 n.67.

115.

Id.

116.

21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(E)(ii), (j)(5)(F)(ii); 21 C.F.R. § 314.108(b)(2).

117.

This five-year new drug exclusivity, however, would not prevent FDA from accepting and approving a duplicate version of the same drug product if the duplicate version is the subject of its own NDA with its own safety and efficacy data. See Small Business Assistance: Frequently Asked Questions for New Drug Product Exclusivity, Food & Drug Admin. (Feb. 11, 2016), https://www.fda.gov/drugs/developmentapprovalprocess/smallbusinessassistance/ucm069962.htm.

118.

U.S. Food & Drug Admin., Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic Equivalence Evaluations (43 ed. 2023), https://www.fda.gov/media/71474/download [hereinafter the "Orange Book"]; see also https://www.accessdata.fda.gov/scripts/cder/ob/index.cfm (searchable version of the Orange Book).

119.

21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(E)(ii), (j)(5)(F)(ii); 21 C.F.R. § 314.108(b)(3). For more information on paragraph IV certifications, see infra "The Hatch-Waxman Act: Patents and Generic Drug Approval."

120.

Under FDA regulations, changes to a drug's label, dosage, strength, or manufacturing methods require an sNDA. 21 C.F.R. § 314.70. sNDAs must include post-market information such as commercial marketing experience and reports in scientific literature, in addition to descriptions and analyses of clinical studies. Id. § 314.50(d)(5)(iv). sNDA sponsors are only eligible for three-year exclusivity because sNDAs amend existing NDAs with approved chemical entities. Id. § 314.108(b).

121.

21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(E)(iii)–(iv), (j)(5)(F)(iii)–(iv).

122.

Compare id. with id. § 355(c)(3)(E)(ii), (j)(5)(F)(ii).

123.

Id. § 355(c)(3)(E)(iii)–(iv), (j)(5)(F)(iii)–(iv).

124.

Id.

125.

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(7)(B).

126.

Id. § 262(k)(7)(A).

127.

This issue has been the subject of discussions between FDA and some lawmakers. See Letter from Rep. Anna G. Eshoo et al., to FDA (Dec. 21, 2010), http://patentdocs.typepad.com/files/letter-to-fda.pdf (signed by Reps. Barton, Eshoo, and Inslee); Letter from Sen. Sherrod Brown et al., to Dr. Margaret Hamburg, Comm'r, FDA (Jan. 24, 2011), http://patentdocs.typepad.com/files/senator-letters-exclusivity.pdf (signed by Sens. Brown, Harkin, McCain, and Schumer). If the exclusivity periods are marketing exclusivities, they would more broadly prevent even an application supported by its own, full clinical trial data from being approved during the 12-year period. More recently, FDA issued guidance that describes the exclusivity periods as limiting approval of an application "referencing [the reference] product," which indicates FDA may consider the exclusivity periods to provide only data exclusivity. U.S. Food & Drug Admin., Interpretation of the "Deemed to be a License" Provision of the Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act of 2009: Guidance for Industry 3 (2018), https://www.fda.gov/ucm/groups/fdagov-public/@fdagov-drugs-gen/documents/document/ucm490264.pdf.

128.

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(7)(C).

129.

ANDA applicants must provide one of four certifications for each listed patent for the RLD. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(vii). Paragraph IV certifications assert that the listed patent has not expired but is invalid or will not be infringed by the generic product. Id. § 355(j)(2)(vii)(IV); see also infra "The Hatch-Waxman Act: Patents and Generic Drug Approval."

130.

See infra "Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs and Biosimilars."

131.

Id.

132.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv), (j)(5)(D)(iii)(II).

133.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv).

134.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(D).

135.

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(6).

136.

Id.

137.

Id.

138.

Pub. L. No. 97-414, § 1, 96 Stat. 2049 (1983) (codified as amended at 21 U.S.C. §§ 360aa–360ff-1).

139.

21 U.S.C. § 360cc(a).

140.

Id. § 360cc. This exclusivity is subject to two exceptions: (1) if the exclusivity holder "cannot ensure the availability of sufficient quantities of the drug to meet the needs of persons with the disease or condition for which the drug was designated"; and (2) if the NDA or BLA holder consents to the approval of another application for the same drug. Id. § 360cc(b).

141.

Id. §§ 360bb, 360cc.

142.

Id. § 360cc; 21 C.F.R. § 316.3(b)(12). However, an NDA or BLA filer may receive exclusivity for an already-approved drug designated for the same rare disease or condition if it can demonstrate clinical superiority. 21 U.S.C. § 360cc(c).

143.

An orphan drug is one that treats a "rare disease or condition" that either (1) "affects less than 200,000 persons in the United States" or (2) "affects more than 200,000 persons in the United States and for which there is no reasonable expectation that the cost of developing and making available in the United States a drug for such disease or condition will be recovered from sales in the United States of such drug." Id. § 360bb(a)(2).

144.

Id.

145.

Id. § 356h(b).

146.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(v).

147.

U.S. Food & Drug Admin., Competitive Generic Therapies (2019), https://www.fda.gov/ucm/groups/fdagov-public/@fdagov-drugs-gen/documents/document/ucm631401.pdf.

148.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(v), (j)(5)(D)(iv); Competitive Generic Therapies, supra note 147, at 18.

149.

21 U.S.C. § 355a(b)–(c); 42 U.S.C. § 262(m).

150.

21 U.S.C. § 355a(b)–(c); 42 U.S.C. § 262(m).

151.

21 U.S.C. § 355a(b)–(c).

152.

U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, cl. 8. See generally Cong. Rech. Serv, ArtI.S8.C8.1 Overview of Congress's Power Over Intellectual Property, Constitution Annotated, https://constitution.congress.gov/browse/essay/artI-S8-C8-1/ALDE_00013060/ (last visited Jan. 29, 2024).

153.

See An Act to Promote the Progress of Useful Arts, Pub. L. No. 1-7, 1 Stat. 109 (1790).

154.

See Patent Act of 1952, Pub. L. No. 82-593, 66 Stat. 792 (codified as amended at 35 U.S.C. §§ 1–390).

155.

Pub. L. No. 112-29, 125 Stat. 284 (2011) (codified in scattered sections of U.S.C. title 35).

156.

See 35 U.S.C. §§ 101–103, 112. For more information on the general requirements to obtain a patent, see Hickey, supra note 28, at 8–17.

157.

See 35 U.S.C. § 101 (allowing patents on "any new and useful . . . composition of matter").

158.

See Margaret K. Kyle, Competition Law, Intellectual Property, and the Pharmaceutical Sector, 81 Antitrust L.J. 1, 2 (2016) ("[A]t least one type of pharmaceutical patent, the product patent on the molecule itself, is particularly hard to invent around.").

159.

See generally Ass'n for Molecular Pathology v. Myriad Genetics, Inc., 569 U.S. 576, 580, 589–96 (2013) (discussing the "natural phenomena" category of patent-ineligible subject matter and holding that a "naturally occurring DNA segment is a product of nature and not patent eligible"); Priti Deka Phukan, Patenting Proteins After Myriad, 23 Fed. Cir. B.J. 619, 621 (2014) (analyzing "whether synthetically produced biological compounds," such as therapeutic proteins and hormones, are patentable "when the synthetic compound is indistinguishable from the naturally occurring compound"). Biologics that derive from biological organisms, but are genetically modified or otherwise modified by man into a non-naturally occurring form, are generally patent-eligible. See Diamond v. Chakrabarty, 447 U.S. 303, 309–10 (1980) (upholding patent on genetically engineered bacterium).

160.

See Kyle, supra note 158, at 6 ("[T]he primary patent on the molecule is rarely the only one associated with a drug. Typically, the innovator (or others) files additional patent applications [that] may cover methods of manufacturing the chemical or biological substance, purified forms, new salts or esters, new uses of the substance, new combinations, new delivery routes, etc.").

161.

Studies have found that active ingredient patents are a minority of pharmaceutical patents. See Amy Kapczynski et al., Polymorphs and Prodrugs and Salts (Oh My!): An Empirical Analysis of "Secondary" Pharmaceutical Patents, 7 PLoS ONE 1, 4–6 (2012) (surveying patents listed in FDA's Orange Book for new chemical entities and finding that secondary patents, such as formulations and methods of use, were more common than active ingredient patents); Tahir Amin & Aaron S. Kesselheim, Secondary Patenting of Branded Pharmaceuticals: A Case Study of How Patents on Two HIV Drugs Could Be Extended for Decades, 31 Health Affs. 2286, 2289 (2012) (finding that only about 1% of the 108 patents covering particular HIV drugs claimed the active ingredient, with around 39% claiming formulations and related chemicals, 32% claiming manufacturing processes, 15% claiming methods of treatment, and 13% claiming other aspects); see also Robin Feldman, May Your Drug Price Be Evergreen, 5 J.L. & Biosci. 590, 637 tbl. 9 (2018) (finding that most patents added to the Orange Book were associated not with newly approved drugs, but with existing ones).

162.

See John R. Thomas, Pharmaceutical Patent Law 46–64 (3d ed. 2015) (overviewing these and other categories of pharmaceutical patent claims).

163.

35 U.S.C. § 101 ("Whoever invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof, may obtain a patent therefor. . . . " (emphasis added)).

164.

KSR Int'l Co. v. Teleflex, Inc., 550 U.S. 398, 417 (2007).

165.

See Gene Quinn, The Successful Inventor: Patenting Improvements, IPWatchdog (May 3, 2014), https://ipwatchdog.com/2014/05/03/the-successful-inventor-patenting-improvements/id=49396/ ("[T]here is not a requirement that an invention actually be an improvement in any real world sense in order for it to be patented . . . when patent attorneys and patent agents talk about an improvement patent we are typically talking about inventions that build upon and/or somehow relate to the prior art.").

166.

See Robert Merges, Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62 Tenn. L. Rev. 75, 80–82 (1994) (analyzing "blocking patents" situation where holder of improvement patent and holder of the original patent need each other's permission before either can practice the improved invention).

167.

Id. at 91; see also Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property Law, 75 Tex. L. Rev. 989, 991, 1010 (1997).

168.

See Lisa Larrimore Ouellette, How Many Patents Does It Take to Make a Drug? Follow-On Pharmaceutical Patents and University Licensing, 17 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 299, 314 (2010) (finding, on average, 2.97 patents listed per drug in FDA's Orange Book); C. Scott Hemphill & Bhaven N. Sampat, Evergreening, Patent Challenges, and Effective Market Life in Pharmaceuticals, 31 J. Health Econ. 327, 330 (2012) finding 2.7 patents per drug for drugs subject to generic entry between 2001 and 2010).

169.

See Dr. Omar Robles et al., Economics in Life Sciences: What the Orange Book Reveals About Trends in Patent Density, Evergreening, and Exclusivity, Nat'l Econ. Rsch. Assocs. (June 26, 2020), https://www.nera.com/content/dam/nera/publications/2020/PUB_LS-Orange-Book_062620.pdf (finding increase in number of over listed patents per drug over 2011-2018, up to a high of 8 patents per drug in 2018); C. Scott Hemphill & Bhaven N. Sampat, When Do Generics Challenge Drug Patents, 8 J. Empirical Legal Stud. 613, 620 fig. 1 (2011) (finding increase in number for Orange Book patents per drug from 2 for drugs approved in 1985 to 4 for drugs approved in 2002).

170.

See infra notes 283284 and accompanying text.

171.

See, e.g., Amy Kapczynski et al., Polymorphs and Prodrugs and Salts (Oh My!): An Empirical Analysis of ''Secondary'' Pharmaceutical Patents, 7 PLoS One 1, 8 tbl. 4 (Dec. 2012).

172.

See I-MAK, Overpatented, Overpriced (Sept. 2022) (finding 74 patents per product, on average, for the top ten best-selling drugs and biologics), https://www.i-mak.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/09/Overpatented-Overpriced-2022-FINAL.pdf. I-MAK's methodology, particularly its use of patent applications in determining potential years of exclusivity, has been criticized by some scholars and Members of Congress. See Adam Mossoff, Unreliable Data Have Infected the Policy Debates over Drug Patents, Hudson Inst. (Jan. 19, 2022), https://www.hudson.org/technology/unreliable-data-have-infected-the-policy-debates-over-drug-patents; Letter from Sen. Thom Tillis to Tahir Amin, Co-Executive Director, I-MAK (Jan 31. 2022), https://ipwatchdog.com/wp-content/uploads/2022/02/1.31.2022-LTR-from-Senator-Tillis-to-IMAK-re-Patent-Data-Sources.pdf.

173.

Mayor and City Council of Baltimore v. AbbVie Inc., 42 F.4th 709, 710 (7th Cir. 2022).

174.

See infra "Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices."

175.

35 U.S.C. § 271(a).

176.

Id. §§ 271, 281, 283–85.

177.

Id. § 261.

178.

License, Black's Law Dictionary (10th ed. 2014); 35 U.S.C. § 271(a).

179.

Leatherman Tool Grp. v. Cooper Indus., Inc., 131 F.3d 1011, 1015 (Fed. Cir. 1997) ("[T]he federal patent laws do not create any affirmative right to make, use, or sell anything.").

180.

See supra "New and Generic Drug Approval" and "Biological Product and Biosimilar Licensure."

181.

35 U.S.C. § 281.

182.

28 U.S.C. § 1338.

183.

Along with district court and the Patent Trial and Appeal Board (PTAB), see infra "The Patent Trial and Appeal Board," the third main forum for patent disputes is the International Trade Commission (ITC), which has authority to conduct administrative trials (called "section 337 investigations") into whether imported goods violate patent and other IP rights. See 19 U.S.C. § 1337. The ITC may issue exclusion orders to stop such goods from entering the United States. See About Section 337, U.S. Int'l Trade Comm., https://www.usitc.gov/intellectual_property/about_section_337.htm (last visited Jan. 26, 2024); see generally Sapna Kumar, The Other Patent Agency: Congressional Regulation of the ITC, 61 Fla. L. Rev. 529, 534–40 (2009) (overviewing ITC procedures). In contrast to the thousands of cases heard by the PTAB and district courts, the ITC typically initiates several dozen section 337 investigations per year. See Section 337 Statistics: Number of New, Completed, and Active Investigations by Fiscal Year, U.S. Int'l Trade Comm. (Oct. 15. 2020), https://www.usitc.gov/intellectual_property/337_statistics_number_new_completed_and_active.htm (reporting 58 new complaints in Fiscal Year 2019).

184.

Patent cases must be brought in a judicial district where the defendant resides (i.e., its state of incorporation), or has a regular and established place of business. See 28 U.S.C. § 1400(b); TC Heartland v. Kraft Foods Grp. Brands, 581 U.S. 258, 262 (2017); In re Cray, 871 F.3d 1355, 1362–64 (Fed. Cir. 2017).

185.

28 U.S.C. § 1295(a)(1).

186.

35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2).

187.

Id. § 154(b)(1).

188.

Id. § 156.

189.

See Eli Lilly & Co. v. Medtronic, Inc., 496 U.S. 661, 670–71 (1990); Merck & Co. v. Hi-Tech Pharmacal Co., 482 F.3d 1317, 1320–21 (Fed. Cir. 2007); see generally Stephanie Plamondon Bair, Adjustments, Extensions, Disclaimers, and Continuations: When Do Patent Term Adjustments Make Sense?, 41 Cap. U. L. Rev. 445 (2013).

190.

See CRS In Focus IF11214, Drug Pricing and the Law: Pharmaceutical Patent Disputes, by Kevin J. Hickey (2019).

191.

See generally Aaron S. Kesselheim et al., Determinants of Market Exclusivity for Prescription Drugs in the United States, 177 JAMA Internal Med. 1658, 1658–59 (2017), https://jamanetwork.com/journals/jamainternalmedicine/fullarticle/2653014. Patent term extensions may compensate for lost effective exclusivity period consumed by regulatory review. See 35 U.S.C. § 156.

192.

See Microsoft Corp. v. i4i Ltd., 564 U.S. 91, 95 (2011).

193.

See infra "Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs and Biosimilars."

194.

See Henry Grabowski et al., Continuing Trends in U.S. Brand-name and Generic Drug Competition, 24 J. Med. Econ. 908, 908 (2021) (finding average market exclusivity period of 14.1 years for all drugs with generic entry between 2017 and 2019, and an average of 13 years for drugs with sales over $250 million); Benjamin N. Rome et al., Market Exclusivity Length for Drugs with New Generic or Biosimilar Competition, 2012–2018, 109 Clinical Pharm & Therapeutics 367 (2020) (finding average market exclusivity of 14.4 years); Erika Lietzan & Kristina M.L. Acri née Lybecker, Distorted Drug Patents, 95 Wash. L. Rev. 1317, 1363 (2020) (finding an average effective market exclusivity period of 12.6 years for drugs with restored patent terms under the Hatch-Waxman Act); Henry Grabowski et al., Updated Trends in U.S. Brand-Name and Generic Drug Competition, 19 J. Med. Econ. 836, 836 (2016) (finding average effective exclusivity period of 13.6 years for all drugs with generic entry between 1995 and 2014, and an average of 12.5 years for drugs with sales over $250 million); Bo Wang et al., Variations in Time of Market Exclusivity Among Top-Selling Prescription Drugs in the United States, 175 JAMA Internal Med. 635, 636 (2015) (finding an average effective market exclusivity of 12.5 years for top-selling drugs between 2000 and 2012); Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 168, at 336 (finding an average market exclusivity of 12.2 years that was "stable" over the decade studied).

195.

See Rome et al., supra note 194, at 368 (finding average effective market exclusivity of 21.56 years for the four biologics in the study).

196.

42 U.S.C. § 262(k)(7).

197.

35 U.S.C. § 282(a)–(b).

198.

Id. § 282(b)(2)–(3); Microsoft Corp. v. i4i Ltd. P'ship, 564 U.S. 91, 95–96 (2011).

199.

See 35 U.S.C. §§ 101, 102–03, 112, 282(b)(2)–(3).

200.

Id. § 282(b)(1).

201.

To prove direct infringement, the plaintiff must show that each element contained in a patent claim is practiced by the alleged infringer, either literally or by an equivalent. Warner-Jenkinson Co. v. Hilton Davis Chem. Co., 520 U.S. 17, 29–30 (1997). Often, whether or not the accused infringer's activities fall within the patent claims depends upon claim construction, that is, how the words used in the patent claims are interpreted. See generally Markman v. Westview Instruments, Inc., 517 U.S. 370, 372–74 (1996); Phillips v. AWH Corp., 415 F.3d 1303, 1312–19 (Fed. Cir. 2005) (en banc).

202.

See Therasense, Inc. v. Becton, Dickinson & Co., 649 F.3d 1276, 1285, 1290–91 (Fed. Cir. 2011) (en banc).

203.

35 U.S.C. §§ 283–284. A judicial declaration of the parties' rights—known as a declaratory judgment—is another important form of relief in patent suits that is sometimes available to patentees or accused infringers. 28 U.S.C. § 2201; see also infra note 263.

204.

35 U.S.C. § 284.

205.

Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co., 56 F.3d 1538, 1545 (Fed. Cir. 1995) (en banc).

206.

Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc., 580 F.3d 1301, 1324 (Fed. Cir. 2009).

207.

35 U.S.C. § 284.

208.

Halo Elecs., Inc. v. Pulse Elecs., Inc., 579 U.S. 93, 104 (2016).

209.

35 U.S.C. § 285.

210.

Octane Fitness, LLC v. ICON Health & Fitness, Inc., 572 U.S. 545, 554 (2014).

211.

35 U.S.C. § 283.

212.

In deciding whether to exercise their discretion to grant a motion for a preliminary injunction, courts weigh four factors: (1) the likelihood that the plaintiff will succeed on the merits of the lawsuit; (2) whether the plaintiff is likely to suffer irreparable harm in the absence of a preliminary injunction; (3) the balance of equities; and (4) whether an injunction is in the public interest. See Titan Tire Corp. v. Case New Holland, Inc., 566 F.3d 1372, 1375–76 (Fed. Cir. 2009) (citing Winter v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 555 U.S. 7, 20 (2008)).

213.

35 U.S.C. § 283. Courts may grant permanent injunctions to remedy patent infringement as justified by traditional equitable principles, but injunctions are not issued solely because the patent holder succeeds in proving infringement. See eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange LLC, 547 U.S. 388, 394 (2006).

214.

See generally Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, Giving the Federal Circuit a Run for Its Money: Challenging Patents in the PTAB, 91 Notre Dame L. Rev. 235, 249 (2015); Hickey, supra note 28, at 24–28 (reviewing PTAB proceedings).

215.

Prior to the AIA, the PTO administered two earlier administrative mechanisms to challenge patents. The first, inter partes reexamination, was generally considered to be "underutilized" and has been replaced by IPR. See Dreyfuss, supra note 214, at 235 n.2; Brian J. Love & Shawn Ambwani, Inter Partes Review: An Early Look at the Numbers, 81 U. Chi. L. Rev. Dialogue 93, 95–96 (2014). The second, ex parte reexamination, which was left unchanged by the AIA, permits the PTO to reopen patent prosecution if a "substantial question of patentability" is presented based on certain prior art cited by the patentee or a third party to the PTO. 35 U.S.C. §§ 301–307.

216.

35 U.S.C. §§ 321–329.

217.

Id. §§ 311–319.

218.

Id. §§ 314, 324.

219.

See PTO, PTAB Trial Statistics: January 2023 IPR, PGR 3 (2023), https://www.uspto.gov/sites/default/files/documents/ptab_aia_20230131_.pdf (98% of recently filed PTAB petitions are IPRs).

220.

See PTO, PTAB Orange Book Patent/Biologic Patent Study 4 (updated Mar. 31, 2023), https://www.uspto.gov/sites/default/files/documents/orange_book_biologics_study_update_thru_march__2023_.pdf.

221.

Id.

222.

Id. at 5–6.

223.

Id. at 10.

224.

Id. § 271.

225.

Compulsory License, Black's Law Dictionary (10th ed. 2014) ("A statutorily created license that allows certain people to pay a royalty and use an invention without the patentee's permission.").

226.

See generally Subhasis Saha, Patent Law and TRIPS: Compulsory Licensing of Patents and Pharmaceuticals, 91 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y 364, 366–67 (2009).

227.

See generally Jesse S. Chui, To What Extent Can Congress Change the Patent Right Without Effecting a Taking?, 34 Hastings Const. L.Q. 447, 462–66 (2007) (reviewing examples of compulsory licensing provisions in existing law, including 28 U.S.C. § 1498, and provisions of the Clean Air Act, Atomic Energy Act, Invention Secrecy Act, and Plant Variety Protection Act).

228.

See Motorola, Inc. v. United States, 729 F.2d 765, 768 (Fed. Cir. 1984); Leesona Corp. v. United States, 599 F.2d 958, 964 (Ct. Cl. 1979).

229.

28 U.S.C. § 1498(a).

230.

Id.

231.

Advanced Software Design Corp. v. Fed. Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 583 F.3d 1371, 1375 (Fed. Cir. 2009) ("[Section 1498] has the effect of removing the threat of injunction. . . . "); Motorola, 729 F.2d at 768 n.3.

232.

Amanda Mitchell, Tamiflu, the Takings Clause, and Compulsory Licenses: An Exploration of the Government's Options for Accessing Medical Patents, 95 Cal. L. Rev. 535, 541–42 (2007) (analogizing section 1498 to a compulsory license).

233.

28 U.S.C. § 1498(a).

234.

Hannah Brennan et al., A Prescription for Excessive Drug Pricing: Leveraging Government Patent Use for Health, 18 Yale J.L. & Tech. 275, 302 (2016) (characterizing the government's use of section 1498 as "routine" and citing a number of examples); but see Adam Mossoff, The False Promise of Breaking Patents to Lower Drug Prices St. John's L. Rev. (forthcoming 2024), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4348499 (manuscript at 7–12) (arguing that section 1498 cannot be used to lower drug prices because it does not apply to goods sold to private parties).

235.

See, e.g., FastShip, LLC v. United States, 892 F.3d 1298 (Fed. Cir. 2018); Beacon Adhesives, Inc. v. United States, 134 Fed. Cl. 26 (2017); Ensign-Bickford Aerospace & Def. Co. v. United States, 118 Fed. Cl. 363 (2014).

236.

Brennan et al., supra note 234, at 303–07 (describing various uses of section 1498 by the federal government to purchase pharmaceutical drugs in the 1960s, but observing this practice "tailed off in the 1970s"). The only recent invocation of section 1498 in the health context occurred in 2001, when Tommy Thompson, then-Secretary of HHS, threatened to (but ultimately did not) rely on this authority to purchase generic versions of Cipro during the anthrax scare. Id. at 303.

237.

See Pub. L. No. 96-517, § 6, 94 Stat. 3015, 3019–27 (1980).

238.

35 U.S.C. § 202(a).

239.

35 U.S.C. § 203(a)(1)–(4). See generally Jennifer Penman & Fran Quigley, Better Late than Never: How the U.S. Government Can and Should Use Bayh-Dole March-in Rights to Respond to the Medicines Access Crisis, 54 Willamette L. Rev. 171, 177–78 (2017). There is a longstanding debate over whether high drug prices could support the exercise of march-in rights. Compare, e.g., Mossoff, supra note 234, at 23–30 (arguing that the statute does not authorize march-in based on high prices) with Peter S. Arno & Michael H. Davis, Why Don't We Enforce Existing Drug Price Controls? The Unrecognized and Unenforced Reasonable Pricing Requirements Imposed upon Patents Deriving in Whole or in Part from Federally Funded Research, 75 Tulane L. Rev. 631, 649–53 (arguing that high prices can be used as the basis to invoke march-in rights). See generally Glenn Kessler, The Claim That the U.S. Government Already Has the Power to Lower Drug Prices, Wash. Post (Sept. 8, 2021), https://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/2021/09/08/claim-that-us-government-already-has-power-lower-drug-prices/ (overviewing this legal debate).

240.

35 U.S.C. § 203(a); Penman & Quigley, supra note 239, at 178.

241.

Penman & Quigley, supra note 239, at 199.

242.

See, e.g., Brennan et al., supra note 234, at 353–54 (arguing that section 1498 should be used to lower prices and increase access to life-saving medicines); Letter from Sen. Elizabeth Warren, Sen, Angus S. King, and Rep. Lloyd Doggett to Xavier Becerra, Secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services (Feb. 17, 2022), https://www.warren.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/2022.02.17%20Letter%20to%20Sec.%20Becerra%20on%20Xtandi%20March-in%20Petition%20(2).pdf (urging the government to exercise march-in rights in order to lower prices for the prostate cancer drug enzalutamide).

243.

See, e.g., Mossoff, supra note 234, at 4-5 (arguing that neither section 1498 nor the Bayh-Dole Act authorizes the use of compulsory licensing to impose price controls); Bayh-Dole Coalition, Issue Brief: March-In Rights Under the Bayh-Dole Act (2023), https://bayhdolecoalition.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/02/BDC-Issue-Brief-March-in-Rights.pdf (arguing that invoking march-in rights to control prices would be highly detrimental to innovation).

244.

See NIST, Request for Information Regarding the Draft Interagency Guidance Framework for Considering the Exercise of March-In Rights, 88 Fed. Reg. 85593 (Dec. 8, 2023).

245.

Press Release, FACT SHEET: Biden-⁠Harris Administration Announces New Actions to Lower Health Care and Prescription Drug Costs by Promoting Competition (Dec. 7, 2023), https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/12/07/fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-announces-new-actions-to-lower-health-care-and-prescription-drug-costs-by-promoting-competition/.

246.

See, e.g., Joel Zinberg, Biden Decides to "March In" on Drug Prices, Wall St. J. (Dec. 12, 2023), https://www.wsj.com/articles/biden-decides-to-march-in-on-drug-patents-price-control-biotech-research-3e327f6b (arguing that the guidance "will stifle pharmaceutical innovation and harm Americans' health"); Joseph Allen, New March-in Guidelines Threaten U.S. Innovation, IPWatchdog (Dec. 10, 2023), https://ipwatchdog.com/2023/12/10/new-march-guidelines-threaten-u-s-innovation/id=170491/.

247.

See generally Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Patents and Regulatory Exclusivity, in The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of the Biopharmaceutical Industry 167–200 (Patricia M. Danzon & Sean Nicholson eds., 2012).

248.

See Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U.S. 470, 480 (1974) ("The patent laws promote [the progress of the useful arts] by offering a right of exclusion for a limited period as an incentive to inventors to risk the often enormous costs in terms of time, research, and development.").

249.

See supra "Regulatory Exclusivities."

250.

See Ward, supra note 31, at 1; Morgan, supra note 26, at 98.

251.

See supra "Rights of Patent Holders."

252.

See infra "The Hatch-Waxman Act: Patents and Generic Drug Approval."

253.

If these existing patents are valid, such deterrence is the object of a functioning patent system. In some cases, patents may deter competition even if a court was likely to hold the patents invalid or not infringed. See generally Christopher R. Leslie, The Anticompetitive Effects of Unenforced Invalid Patents, 91 Minn. L. Rev. 101, 113–39 (2006) (arguing that even invalid patents can deter market entry of competitors based on fear of litigation and high litigation costs); Rebecca S. Eisenberg & Daniel A. Crane, Patent Punting: How FDA and Antitrust Courts Undermine the Hatch-Waxman Act to Avoid Dealing with Patents, 21 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 197, 260–62 (2015) (arguing that pharmaceutical companies may deter or delay competition through assertion of "irrelevant" patents).

254.

Eli Lilly & Co. v. Medtronic, Inc., 496 U.S. 661, 669 (1990).

255.

Id. at 669–70.

256.

Id. at 670; 35 U.S.C. § 156. The patent term extension applies, among other things, to patents that claim a drug or medical device, a method of using a drug or medical device, or a method of manufacturing a drug or medical device. See id. § 156(a), (f)(1).

257.

Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel Co., 376 U.S. 225, 230 (1964) ("[W]hen the patent expires the monopoly created by it expires, too, and the right to make the article . . . passes to the public.").

258.

See, e.g., Roche Prods. v. Bolar Pharm. Co., 733 F.2d 858, 863 (Fed. Cir. 1984).

259.

Eli Lilly, 496 U.S. at 670.

260.

Id.

261.

35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(1); Merck KGaA v. Integra Lifescis. I, Ltd., 545 U.S. 193, 200 (2005) (describing this provision as a "safe harbor").

262.

Eli Lilly, 496 U.S. at 678.

263.

Even in the absence of an actual act of infringement, either party could generally file a lawsuit seeking a declaratory judgment, asking a court to "declare the rights and other legal relations" between the parties, such as whether a patent is invalid or noninfringed. 28 U.S.C. § 2201(a). For a court to have jurisdiction, there must be an actual and "substantial controversy, between parties having adverse legal interests, of sufficient immediacy and reality to warrant the issuance of a declaratory judgment." MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 549 U.S. 118, 127 (2007) (quoting Md. Cas. Co. v. Pac. Coal & Oil Co., 312 U.S. 270, 273 (1941)); see also Teva Pharm. USA, Inc. v. Novartis Pharm. Corp., 482 F.3d 1330, 1336–39 (Fed. Cir. 2007). In addition, both the Hatch-Waxman Act and the BPCIA limit declaratory judgement jurisdiction for pharmaceutical patents in some circumstances. 28 U.S.C. § 2201(b).

264.

See Natalie M. Derzko, The Impact of Recent Reforms of the Hatch-Waxman Scheme on Orange Book Strategic Behavior and Pharmaceutical Innovation, 45 IDEA: Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 165, 239 (2005) ("From society's perspective, early resolution of such patent disputes is generally considered beneficial since it helps clear the way for generic drug entry if a patent is in fact invalid. . . . Such resolution provides an early signal to the generic company of this fact before substantial resources are expended in launching, marketing and selling its generic copy of the brand-name drug.").

265.

See id. at 239–40; Laura J. Robinson, Analysis of Recent Proposals to Reconfigure Hatch-Waxman, 11 J. Intell. Prop. L. 47, 78 (2003) ("[If patent issues are not resolved,] the generic [company] cannot go to market without risking a later infringement suit with substantial damages.").

266.

Eli Lilly, 496 U.S. at 678; see 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(2)(A).

267.

35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(2)(C).

268.

Eli Lilly, 496 U.S. at 678; see generally Elizabeth Stotland Weiswasser & Scott D. Danzis, The Hatch-Waxman Act: History, Structure, and Legacy, 71 Antitrust L.J. 585, 595 (2003) ("The Hatch-Waxman Act created a system that enabled the resolution of patent infringement disputes prior to the entry of generic competition.").

269.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b)(1); see also 21 C.F.R. § 314.53(b).

270.

See Orange Book, supra note 118.

271.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii). While this summary discusses the patent dispute procedures with respect to an ANDA, NDAs that rely on reports and data to which they have no right of reference (e.g., published studies) are subject to a parallel certification and notification process. See id. § 355(b)(2)–(3), (c)(3).

272.

With respect to patents that claim a method of using a drug, the generic applicant may file a "section viii" statement when the applicant is seeking approval only for a use that is not claimed in a listed patent. Id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(viii). See infra "Section viii Statements and 'Skinny Labels'".

273.

Id. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(I)–(IV).

274.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(i).

275.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(ii).

276.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii); Caraco Pharm. Labs., Ltd. v. Novo Nordisk A/S, 566 U.S. 399, 407 (2012).

277.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(B)(i)–(iv).

278.

Id. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii).

279.

Id. § 335(j)(5)(C)(i); see generally Caraco Pharm., 527 F.3d at 1285. In civil actions for patent certainty, federal courts have subject-matter jurisdiction so long as it is "consistent with the Constitution." 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(5).

280.

See 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii); Caraco Pharm., 566 U.S. at 407–08. Following amendments to the Hatch-Waxman Act in 2003, the NDA holder may receive one 30-month stay based on patents listed in the Orange Book with respect to an ANDA. See 21 U.S.C. § 355(c)(3)(C), (j)(5)(B)(iii); Colleen Kelly, The Balance Between Innovation and Competition: The Hatch-Waxman Act, the 2003 Amendments, and Beyond, 66 Food & Drug L.J. 417, 439 (2011) ("[The 2003 amendments] effectively limited an innovator company to one thirty-month stay per ANDA.").

281.

21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii)(I).

282.

35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(4)(A); 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii)(II). If a judgment of infringement is appealed by the ANDA filer and reversed by the court of appeals (i.e., the Federal Circuit), FDA may approve the application as of the date of an appellate decision in favor of the ANDA filer. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(II)(aa)(AA).

283.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b)(1). Additionally, the listed patents must be such that "a claim of patent infringement could reasonably be asserted if a person not licensed by the owner engaged in the manufacture, use, or sale of the drug." Id.

284.

21 C.F.R. § 314.53(b)(1).

285.

See Applications for FDA Approval to Market a New Drug: Patent Submission and Listing Requirements and Application of 30-Month Stays on Approval of Abbreviated New Drug Applications Certifying That a Patent Claiming a Drug Is Invalid or Will Not Be Infringed, 68 Fed. Reg. 36676, 36683 (June 18, 2003) (codified at 21 C.F.R. pt. 314) ("[FDA's] patent listing role remains ministerial.") (citing aaiPharma Inc. v. Thompson, 296 F.3d 227, 242–43 (4th Cir. 2002)).

286.

See, e.g., Eisenberg & Crane, supra note 253, at 260 (arguing that "the lack of administrative oversight" by FDA "has allowed innovators to defer competition through the listing of irrelevant patents"). Some Members of Congress have echoed this criticism and urged FDA to clarify the types of patents that can be listed in the Orange Book and to enforce those guidelines. See, e.g., Letter from Sen. Elizabeth Warren and Rep. Pramila Jayapal to Dr. Robert M. Califf, Comm'r of FDA, (Aug. 28, 2023), https://www.warren.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/2023.08.28%20Letter%20to%20FDA%20re%20drug%20patents.pdf.

287.

21 C.F.R. § 314.53(f)(1). Generally, FDA will not change the patent information in the Orange Book unless the NDA holder amends or corrects the information in response to a patent listing dispute. Id. § 314.53(f)(1)(i); see generally Ashley M. Winkler et al., Requirements, Benefits, and Possible Consequences of Listing Patents in the FDA's Orange Book, BNA Pharm. L. & Indus. Rep. 4–5 (July 3, 2018), https://www.finnegan.com/print/content/65249/Requirements-Benefits-and-Possible-Consequences-of-Listing-Patents-in-FDAs-Orange-Book.pdf. An ANDA filer may also make a counterclaim in patent infringement litigation to correct or delete patent information listed by the NDA holder. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(C)(ii)(I).

288.

See Winkler et al., supra note 287, at 3 ("Having a patent listed in the Orange Book provides significant benefits to the NDA holder.").

289.

See id. at 4–5 (discussing the "possible consequences" of not listing or late listing, including the potential loss of the 30-month stay, but not a loss of patent rights); Brian D. Coggio & Ron Vogel, Can Reference Sponsor Forfeit Right to Sue under BPCIA?, Law360 (July 25, 2016), https://www.law360.com/articles/820197, at n.32 ("It is worth noting that the Hatch Waxman Act does not have a 'list it or lose it' provision. A patentee can choose to assert any patents listed in the Orange Book, but it does not forfeit the right to later assert patents that were not part of the original litigation.").

290.

See, e.g., Jazz Pharms. v. Avadel CNS Pharms., 60 F.4th 1373 (Fed. Cir. 2023) (holding that patent on a computer-implemented REMS system should not have been listed in the Orange Book because it did not claim a method of using a drug); In re Lantus Direct Purchaser Antitrust Litig., 950 F.3d 1, 8 (1st Cir. 2020) (holding that patent on device used in an injector should not have been listed in Orange Book because the patent claims "do not mention the drug").

291.

FDA, Report to Congress: The Listing of Patent Information in the Orange Book ii (2022), https://www.fda.gov/media/155200/download.

292.

FTC, Federal Trade Commission Statement Concerning Brand Drug Manufacturers' Improper Listing of Patents in the Orange Book (Sept. 14, 2023), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/ftc_gov/pdf/p239900orangebookpolicystatement092023.pdf.

293.

Id.

294.

Id. at 4.

295.

Press Release, FTC, FTC Challenges More Than 100 Patents as Improperly Listed in the FDA's Orange Book (Nov. 7, 2023), https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/news/press-releases/2023/11/ftc-challenges-more-100-patents-improperly-listed-fdas-orange-book. Some companies have responded to the FTC's actions by removing these patents from the Orange Book. See Kate Goodwin, Three Companies Relent to FTC Demands, Delist Patents from FDA's Orange Book, BioSpace (Dev. 22, 2023), https://www.biospace.com/article/three-companies-relent-to-ftc-demands-delist-patents-from-fda-s-orange-book-/.

296.

21 C.F.R. § 314.53(c)(2)(i)(O), (ii)(P).

297.

See id. § 314.53(c)(2)(ii)(P)(3).

298.

See id. § 314.53(c)(2)(ii)(P)(2).

299.

See Caraco Pharm. Labs v. Novo Nordisk, 566 U.S. 399, 405 (2012).

300.

Id. at 405–06; see generally aaiPharma Inc. v. Thompson, 296 F.3d 227, 239–41 (4th Cir. 2002).

301.

21 U.S.C. § 355(b)(2)(B), (j)(2)(A)(viii).

302.

Id.; see also Caraco Pharm., 566 U.S. at 406.

303.

See 21 C.F.R. § 314.94(a)(8)(iv).

304.

See Caraco Pharm., 566 U.S. at 406 ("If the ANDA applicant [uses section (vii)], it will propose labeling for the generic drug that 'carves out' from the brand's approved label the still-patented methods of use."); GSK v. Teva Pharms. USA, 7 F.4th 1320, 1328 (Fed. Cir. 2021) (using the term "skinny label").

305.

AstraZeneca LP v. Apotex, Inc., 633 F.3d 1042, 1046 (Fed. Cir. 2010).

306.

See Caraco Pharm., 566 U.S. at 426–28 (Sotomayor, J., concurring); S. 1128, 118th Cong. (proposing new cause of action to correct Orange Book use codes).

307.

See GlaxoSmithKline LLC v. Teva Pharms. USA, Inc., 7 F.4th 1320, 1338 (Fed. Cir. 2021), cert. denied sub nom. Teva Pharms. USA, Inc. v. Glaxo-SmithKline LLC, 143 S. Ct. 2483 (2023).

308.

See, e.g., Sara W. Koblitz, Ding Dong: Is the Skinny Label (Effectively) Dead?, FDA Law Blog (Sept. 7, 2021), https://www.thefdalawblog.com/2021/09/ding-dong-is-the-skinny-label-effectively-dead/ (arguing that uncertainty created by the Federal Circuit's decision in GSK v. Teva renders the process too uncertain for a "risk-averse generic sponsor").

309.

See supra "Biological Product and Biosimilar Licensure."

310.

See 42 U.S.C. § 262(a); Background Information: Lists of Licensed Biological Products with Reference Product Exclusivity and Biosimilarity or Interchangeability Evaluations (Purple Book), U.S. Food & Drug Admin. (Aug. 3, 2020), https://www.fda.gov/drugs/biosimilars/background-information-list-licensed-biological-products-reference-product-exclusivity-and [hereinafter Purple Book Background Information].

311.

Pub. L. No. 116-260, div. BB, tit. III, subtit. C, § 325(a), 134 Stat. 2936.

312.

Purple Book: Lists of Licensed Biological Products with Reference Product Exclusivity and Biosimilarity or Interchangeability Evaluations, Food & Drug Admin. (last updated Oct. 24, 2023), https://purplebooksearch.fda.gov/ [hereinafter Purple Book].

313.

See 42 U.S.C. § 262(l).

314.

Sandoz Inc. v. Amgen Inc., 582 U.S. 1, 8 (2017) (holding that injunctive relief to compel participation in the patent dance is not available under federal law); Amgen Inc. v. Sandoz Inc., 877 F.3d 1315, 1326–30 (Fed. Cir. 2017) (holding that the BPCIA preempts state law remedies for failure to commence the patent dance).

315.

Sandoz, 582 U.S. at 10.

316.

Id.

317.

42 U.S.C. § 262(l)(2).

318.

Sandoz, 582 U.S. at 7–9.

319.

Id. at 8.

320.

42 U.S.C. § 262(l)(3)(A).

321.

Id. § 262(l)(3)(B)(ii)–(iii). The biosimilar applicant may also choose to supplement the reference product sponsor's list of relevant patents. See id. § 262(l)(3)(B)(i).

322.

Id. § 262(l)(3)(C).

323.

Id. § 262(l)(4)(A), (l)(6). The BPCIA provides a procedure for a simultaneous exchange of patent lists if the parties cannot agree on the patents that should be litigated immediately. Id. § 262(l)(5).

324.

Id. § 262(l)(6).

325.

Id. § 262(l)(8)(A).

326.

Id. § 262(l)(8)(B).

327.

Sandoz Inc. v. Amgen Inc., 582 U.S. 1, 19 (2017).

328.

See Thomas J. Sullivan, The Patent Dance, Eur. Biopharm. Rev. 70–74 (July 2018), https://www.finnegan.com/en/insights/articles/the-patent-dance-article.html ("A second mechanism to shorten a suit under the BPCIA would be to collapse the two phases of litigation . . . where the biosimilar applicant provides its 180-day notice of commercial marketing contemporaneously with its notification to the reference product sponsor of its [biosimilar application.]").

329.

Sandoz, 582 U.S. at 16.

330.

Id.; see 42 U.S.C. § 262(l)(9)(C).

331.

Sandoz, 582 U.S. at 16.

332.

See generally Limin Zheng, Shall We (Patent) Dance?—Key Considerations for Biosimilar Applicants, Biosimilar Dev. (Feb. 27, 2018), https://www.biosimilardevelopment.com/doc/shall-we-patent-dance-key-considerations-for-biosimilar-applicants-0001.

333.

42 U.S.C. § 262(l)(3)(A)(i).

334.

See Krista Hessler Carver et al., An Unofficial Legislative History of the Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act of 2009, 65 Food & Drug L.J. 671, 760 (2010) (describing this provision as the "list it or lose it" requirement); Coggio & Vogel, supra note 289 (same).

335.

35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(6)(C). The statute is unclear as to whether the holder of a patent that was not timely listed loses his right to sue the biosimilar applicant only during the premarketing period (i.e., only with respect to the "artificial" act of infringement), or forfeits the right to sue on that patent for post-marketing infringement as well. See Coggio & Vogel, supra note 289 (analyzing the potential ambiguity as to whether the patentee is "precluded from asserting infringement of the nonlisted patent(s) under all subsections of section 271, or just subsection 271(e)(2)"); but see Hessler Carver et al., supra note 334, at 760 (describing the "list it or lose it" provision as reaching infringements both "before or after marketing of the biosimilar").

336.

Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 895 (2007) ("[T]he antitrust laws are designed primarily to protect interbrand competition, from which lower prices can later result."); State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 15 (1997) ("Our analysis is also guided by our general view that the primary purpose of the antitrust laws is to protect interbrand competition.").

337.

CRS In Focus IF11234, Antitrust Law: An Introduction, by Jay B. Sykes (2022).

338.

Id.

339.

15 U.S.C. §§ 1–2; see infra "Pharmaceutical Patenting Practices."

340.

15 U.S.C. § 1.

341.

See, e.g., NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 98 (1984).

342.

United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 387 (1956).

343.

United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 607 (1972).

344.

NCAA, 468 U.S. at 99, 103–04.

345.

Leegin Creative Leather Prods. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 886 (2007) (internal citations omitted).

346.

See, e.g., United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 218 (1940); NCAA, 468 U.S. at 99, 103–04; Stop & Shop Supermarket Co. v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of R.I., 373 F.3d 57, 61 (1st Cir. 2004).

347.

Stop & Shop Supermarket Co., 373 F.3d at 61; see also Leegin Creative Leather Prods., 551 U.S. at 886; Nat'l Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692–93 (1978).

348.

See Daniel Crane, Antitrust 53–56 (2014); see also Herbert Hovenkamp, The Rule of Reason, 70 Fla. L. Rev. 81, 103 (2018) (collecting cases).

349.

See Crane, supra note 348, at 53–54; Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and Its Practice 103 (5th ed. 2015). The Supreme Court has explained that a properly defined market includes the product at issue and its substitutes—that is, other products that are "reasonably interchangebl[e]" with the relevant product. See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962). Stated differently, whether two products compete in the same market depends on the extent to which an increase in the price of one product in a given geographic region would cause consumers to purchase the other product instead. Hovenkamp, supra, at 111–17.

350.

See Crane, supra note 348, at 54; Hovenkamp, supra note 349, at 103.

351.

See Crane, supra note 348, at 54; Hovenkamp, supra note 349, at 104.

352.

Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 526 U.S. 756, 770 (1999).

353.

Id. at 780 (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).

354.

Id. at 770.

355.

15 U.S.C. § 2.

356.

Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004).

357.

Id. (quoting United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570–71 (1966)).

358.

Schneiderman v. Actavis PLC, 787 F.3d 638, 651 (2d Cir. 2015).

359.

Id. at 652.

360.

See The Antitrust Laws, U.S. Dep't of Justice, https://www.justice.gov/atr/antitrust-laws-and-you (last visited Jan. 25, 2024); The Enforcers, U.S. Fed. Trade Comm'n, https://www.ftc.gov/tips-advice/competition-guidance/guide-antitrust-laws/enforcers (last visited Jan. 25, 2024) [hereinafter The Enforcers].

361.

15 U.S.C. § 45; FTC v. Cement Inst., 333 U.S. 683, 690 (1948) (holding that the FTC may pursue violations of the Sherman Act as unfair methods of competition); FTC v. Motion Picture Advert. Serv. Co., 344 U.S. 392, 394 (1953) ("The 'Unfair methods of competition', which are condemned by § 5(a) of the [FTC] Act, are not confined to those that were illegal at common law or that were condemned by the Sherman Act.").

362.

The Enforcers, supra note 360.

363.

Id. ("If the FTC believes that a person or company has violated the law or that a proposed merger may violate the law, the agency may attempt to obtain voluntary compliance by entering into a consent order with the company. A company that signs a consent order need not admit that it violated the law, but it must agree to stop the disputed practices outlined in an accompanying complaint or take certain steps to resolve the anticompetitive aspects of its proposed merger.").

364.

Id. ("If a consent agreement cannot be reached, the FTC may issue an administrative complaint and/or seek injunctive relief in the federal courts.").

365.

Id. ("The FTC's administrative complaints initiate a formal proceeding that is much like a federal court trial but before an administrative law judge: evidence is submitted, testimony is heard, and witnesses are examined and cross-examined.").

366.

Id. ("If a law violation is found, a cease and desist order may be issued. An initial decision by an administrative law judge may be appealed to the Commission. Final decisions issued by the Commission may be appealed to a U.S. Court of Appeals and, ultimately, to the U.S. Supreme Court.").

367.

Peter Thomas Luce, Hiding Behind Borders in a Borderless World: Extraterritoriality Doctrine and the Inadequacy of U.S. Software Patent Protections in a Networked Economy, 10 Tul. J. Tech. & Intell. Prop. 259, 280 n.118 (2007) ("If the patent is legitimate, the patent holder would be a patent fool if he did not protect his rights to the fullest extent of the law.").

368.

See, e.g., Christopher M. Holman et al., Patentability Standard for Follow-On Pharmaceutical Innovation, 37 Biotech. L. Rep. 131 (2018); Erika Lietzan, The Evergreening Myth, 43 Regulation 24 (Fall 2020), https://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/2020-09/regulation-v43n3-4.pdf; Christopher M. Holman, Congress Should Decline Ill-Advised Legislative Proposals Aimed at Evergreening of Pharmaceutical Patent Protection, 51 U. Pac. L. Rev. 493 (2020).

369.

See, e.g., Michael A. Carrier & Carl J. Minniti III, Biologics: The New Antitrust Frontier, 2018 U. Ill. L. Rev. 1, 3 (2018).

370.

Eisenberg, supra note 26, at 354; Julian W. Marrs, Forever Green? An Examination of Pharmaceutical Patent Extensions, 18 Or. Rev. Int'l L. 81, 83–89 (2016); Michael Enzo Furrow, Pharmaceutical Patent Life-Cycle Management After KSR v. Teleflex, 63 Food & Drug L.J. 275, 276 (2008). Although the literature is not entirely consistent regarding the definition of "evergreening," sometimes equating it with other patenting practices, see, e.g., Michael A. Carrier & Steve D. Shadowen, Product Hopping: A New Framework, 92 Notre Dame L. Rev. 167, 171 (2016) (equating evergreening with "product hopping"), this report uses the term to refer to using later-filed patents to extend the length of a product's effective protection.

371.

See, e.g., Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 171–72.

372.

Cynthia Koons, This Shield of Patents Protects the World's Best-Selling Drug, Bloomberg Businessweek (Sept. 7, 2017), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-09-07/this-shield-of-patents-protects-the-world-s-best-selling-drug (using the term "patent thicket" to refer to a large patent portfolio amassed on one product by a single biologics manufacturer); Robin Feldman, "One-and-Done" for New Drugs Could Cut Patent Thickets and Boost Generic Competition, STAT (Feb. 11, 2019), https://www.statnews.com/2019/02/11/drug-patent-protection-one-done/ ("[D]rug companies build massive patent walls around their products, extending the protection over and over again.").

373.

Failure to Launch: Patent Abuse Blocks Access to Biosimilars for America's Patients, Biosimilars Council 8 (June 2019), https://www.biosimilarscouncil.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/06/Biosimilars-Council-White-Paper-Failure-to-Launch-June-2019.pdf [hereinafter Failure to Launch] (estimating it would cost $3 million per patent to challenge the patent thicket surrounding the biologic Humira).

374.

Michael A. Carrier, A Real-World Analysis of Pharmaceutical Settlements: The Missing Dimension of Product Hopping, 62 Fla. L. Rev. 1009, 1014 (2010) (stating the 180-day exclusivity period "has resulted in numerous settlements between brand firms and first-filing generic companies").

375.

Erik Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law and Settlement Design, 32 Harv. J.L. & Tech. 417, 434 (2019) ("[T]he brand-name firm agrees to give a 'reverse payment' (conventionally a cash lump sum) to the generic firm. In exchange, the latter agrees to terminate its challenge and delay its entry into the market for some number of years, often until soon before the patent expires." (footnote omitted)).

376.

See id.

377.

Eisenberg, supra note 26, at 354; see also Marrs, supra note 370, at 83–89; Furrow, supra note 370, at 276.

378.

See supra "Types of Pharmaceutical Patent Claims."

379.

Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 169, at 619–20; see also sources cited supra note 169.

380.

See sources cited supra note 168.

381.

See supra notes 171172 and accompanying text.

382.

See Feldman, supra note 161, at 597.

383.

Staff of H. Comm. on Oversight & Reform, Drug Pricing Investigation: Celgene and Bristol Myers Squibb—Revlimid i (Sept. 30, 2020), https://oversightdemocrats.house.gov/sites/democrats.oversight.house.gov/files/Celgene%20BMS%20Staff%20Report%2009-30-2020.pdf.

384.

Id. at 20.

385.

Staff of H. Comm. on Oversight & Reform, Drug Pricing Investigation: Amgen—Enbrel and Sensipar 25 (Sept. 30, 2020), https://oversightdemocrats.house.gov/sites/democrats.oversight.house.gov/files/Amgen%20Staff%20Report%2010-1-20.pdf.

386.

See supra "Types of Pharmaceutical Patent Claims."

387.

See, e.g., Marrs, supra note 370, at 83–86; Feldman & Frondorf, supra note 9, at 555 ("Pharmaceutical company behavior [such as evergreening] that extends the period in which the company can hold off competition runs contrary to the patent bargain [leading to] losses to society in the form of higher prices."); Feldman, supra note 161, at 590 (criticizing drug companies for "recycling and repurposing old [medicines]" to stifle competition).

388.

See, e.g., Aaron S. Kesselheim, Think Globally, Prescribe Locally: How Rational Pharmaceutical Policy in the U.S. Can Improve Global Access to Essential Medicines, 34 Am. J.L. & Med. 125, 136 (2008) ("Loose interpretation of patent laws has permitted patent evergreening, where overly broad or otherwise inappropriate patents have been granted on peripheral aspects of pharmaceutical products . . . ."); Eisenberg, supra note 26, at 354 (noting that although "innovating firms have succeeded in getting [secondary] patents issued by the PTO," "[t]he industry's track record in actually winning these infringement claims . . . has been considerably worse").

389.

Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 168, at 334 (finding secondary patents relating to ancillary aspects of a drug are more frequently challenged by generics).

390.

Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 169, at 621 ("These patents, though weak, nevertheless have the effect of making the patent portfolio stronger. If they overlap in duration with a strong composition of matter patent, they provide an additional barrier to generic entry prior to expiration of the strong patent, since the generic must defeat the weak patent in addition to the strong one.").

391.

Am. Intell. Property L. Ass'n, 2019 Report of the Economic Survey 51 (Sept,. 2019), https://ipwatchdog.com/wp-content/uploads/2021/08/AIPLA-Report-of-the-Economic-Survey-Relevant-Excerpts.pdf.

392.

See Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 169, at 621.

393.

Id.; 35 U.S.C. § 103.

394.

See Holman et al., supra note 368, at 132–33 (rejecting "false dichotomy" between primary and secondary pharmaceutical patents and noting that "secondary patents invariably will be narrower . . . because these later-filed patents must define an invention that is novel and not obvious over the older pharmaceutical product").

395.

Id.

396.

Christopher M. Holman et al., Patentability Standards for Follow-On Pharmaceutical Innovation, 37 Biotech. L. Rep. 131, 134 (2018).

397.

Id.

398.

Id.

399.

Id.

400.

See Leitzan, supra note 368, at 24–29 (rejecting the "myth" of evergreening and arguing that usage of the term is problematic).

401.

Holman et al., supra note 396, at 135.

402.

Id.

403.

Id.

404.

Hemphill & Sampat, supra note 168, at 330. "Nominal patent term" is "the time between brand approval and expiration of the last expiring patent." Id.

405.

Michiko Morris, supra note 6, at 267–68.

406.

See Holman et al., supra note 368, at 132.

407.

Id.

408.

Id. at 137–38.

409.

See supra "The Patent Trial and Appeal Board."

410.

H.R. Rep. No. 112-98, at 39–40 (2011).

411.

35 U.S.C. § 311. A similar proceeding, PGR, allows for challenges in the initial nine months after the patent issues. Id. §§ 321–329.

412.

Id. § 314(a).

413.

Id. § 316(e).

414.

Microsoft Corp. v. i4i Ltd. P'ship, 564 U.S. 91, 95 (2011).

415.

35 U.S.C. § 316(e)(11).

416.

Stephen Yelderman, Prior Art in Inter Partes Review, 104 Iowa L. Rev. 2705, 2706 (2019).

417.

35 U.S.C. § 103.

418.

KSR Int'l Co. v. Teleflex Inc., 550 U.S. 398, 416 (2007).

419.

Id. at 417–22.

420.

Id. at 417.

421.

Id.

422.

35 U.S.C. § 101 ("Whoever invents or discovers any new and useful process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof, may obtain a patent therefor, subject to the conditions and requirements of this title." (emphasis added)).

423.

Sun Pharm. Indus., Ltd. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 611 F.3d 1381, 1384–85 (Fed. Cir. 2010).

424.

Id.

425.

Id.

426.

Id.

427.

Id.

428.

See, e.g., Gilead Sci., Inc. v. Natco Pharma Ltd., 753 F.3d 1208, 1210 (Fed. Cir. 2014); STC.UNM v. Intel Corp., 754 F.3d 940, 942 (Fed. Cir. 2014); see generally 35 U.S.C. § 253(b); 37 C.F.R. § 1.321.

429.

Letter from Janet Woodcock, Acting Comm'r of FDA, to Andrew Hirschfeld, Acting Director of USPTO (Sept. 10, 2021), https://www.fda.gov/about-fda/reports/fda-uspto-collaboration-initiatives/.

430.

Letter from Katherine K. Vidal, Director of USPTO, to Robert M. Califf, Comm'r of FDA at 6 (July 6, 2022), https://www.uspto.gov/sites/default/files/documents/PTO-FDA-nextsteps-7-6-2022.pdf.

431.

USPTO, Request for Comments on USPTO Initiatives to Ensure the Robustness and Reliability of Patent Rights, 87 Fed. Reg. 60130, 60133–34 (Oct. 4, 2022) USPTO, Request for Comments on USPTO Initiatives To Ensure the Robustness and Reliability of Patent Rights, 87 Fed. Reg. 66282 (Nov. 3, 2022); USPTO, Request for Comments on USPTO Initiatives to Ensure the Robustness and Reliability of Patent Rights, 88 Fed. Reg. 9492 (Feb. 14, 2023).

432.

This term was coined by Professor Herbert Hovenkamp in the early 2000s. See Alan Devlin, Exclusionary Strategies in the Hatch-Waxman Context, 2007 Mich. St. L. Rev. 631, 658 (2007) (citing Herbert Hovenkamp et al., IP and Antitrust: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles Applied to Intellectual Property Law § 12.5 (2002)).

433.

See generally Feldman & Frondorf, supra note 9, at 527–30; Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 171–73; Tobin Klusty, A Legal Text for the Pharmaceutical Company Practice of "Product Hopping," 17 Am. Med. Ass'n J. Ethics 760, 760 (2015).

434.

See Steve D. Shadowen et al., Anticompetitive Product Changes in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 41 Rutgers L.J. 1, 25 (2009) (categorizing pharmaceutical reformulations); Feldman & Frondorf, supra note 9, at 529–32 (reviewing examples of product hopping); Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 172 (same).

435.

Shadowen et al., supra note 434, at 3 ("In addition to physically altering the product, manufacturers often also: (1) switch promotional efforts from the original product to the reformulated product; (2) introduce the redesigned product before generic entry; or (3) withdraw the original product from the market."); accord Feldman & Frondorf, supra note 9, at 527–29.

436.

Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 192.

437.

432 F. Supp. 2d 408 (D. Del. 2006).

438.

Id. at 415.

439.

Id. at 415–17. Making these types of changes may render any current generic version of a branded drug no longer therapeutically equivalent to the branded version, thus generally preventing a pharmacist from substituting the generic version for the branded version. See infra notes 451456 and accompanying text.

440.

Abbott Labs., 432 F. Supp. 2d at 415–17 A Delaware district court determined these allegations were sufficient to support an antitrust claim. Id. at 419–33.

441.

787 F.3d 638 (2d Cir. 2015). Since this case, Actavis has changed its name to Allergan. Andrew Berg, Actavis Moves to Adopt New "Allergan" Corporate Name, R&D (May 20, 2016), https://www.rdmag.com/news/2016/05/actavis-moves-adopt-new-allergan-corporate-name.

442.

Schneiderman, 787 F.3d at 642.

443.

Id.

444.

Id. at 647.

445.

Id. at 648.

446.

Id. (footnote omitted).

447.

Id.

448.

Schneiderman v. Actavis PLC, 787 F.3d 638, 648 (2d Cir. 2015). The district court determined that Actavis's conduct was anticompetitive and issued a preliminary injunction ordering Actavis to make IR available on the same terms and conditions as before. Id. at 662. The Second Circuit affirmed the district court's determination and the preliminary injunction, although the court determined that it was only the hard switch that crossed the line into illegal behavior. Id. at 654. The court reasoned that as long as both IR and XR were on the market with generic drugs on the horizon, doctors and patients could evaluate whether the benefits of switching to once-daily XR outweighed the increased costs as compared to the generic form of IR. Id. at 655.

449.

See, e.g., Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 168 ("The concern with [product hopping] is that some of these switches can significantly decrease consumer welfare, impairing competition from generic drugs to an extent that greatly exceeds any gains from the 'improved' branded product."); Justine Amy Park, Product Hopping: Antitrust Liability and a Per Se Rule, 35 Cardozo Arts & Ent. L.J. 745, 773 (2017) ("The use of product hopping to circumvent the entry of generic competitors is a gross violation of [antitrust law] and encourages brand name manufacturers to thinly disguise their products as innovative while maintaining patent monopolies on products."); Jessie Cheng, An Antitrust Analysis of Product Hopping in the Pharmaceutical Industry, 108 Colum. L. Rev. 1471, 1472 (2008) ("[P]roduct hopping amounts to little more than a thinly disguised scheme to manipulate the pharmaceutical industry's regulatory system and frustrate generic competition.").

450.

Vikram Iyengar, Should Pharmaceutical Product Hopping Be Subject to Antitrust Scrutiny?, 97 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y 663, 669–70 (2015) ("If the brand firm withdraws its existing product from pharmacy shelves and convinces doctors to write prescriptions for its new product, the market for the generic collapses."); Shadowen et al., supra note 434, at 7–18 (describing how the regulatory and economic context creates "price disconnect" that prevents generics from effectively competing on price following a product reformulation).

451.

Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 175. Questions have been raised as to whether DPS laws are still important, considering the increased power of drug plans and pharmacy benefit managers. See, e.g., Joanna Shepherd, Deterring Innovation: New York v. Actavis and the Duty to Subsidize Competitors' Market Entry, 17 Minn. J. of L., Sci. & Tech. 663, 688–92 (2016) (arguing pharmacy benefit managers and insurers have adopted methods for providing patients with less-expensive alternatives to branded pharmaceuticals).

452.

Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 175.

453.

Id.

454.

Id.

455.

Id. at 176.

456.

Id.

457.

Shepherd, supra note 451, at 668; see also Tyler J. Klein, Antitrust Enforcement Against Pharmaceutical Product Hopping: Protecting Consumers or Reaching Too Far?, 10 St. Louis U. J. Health L. & Pol'y 213 (2016).

458.

Shepherd, supra note 451, at 668.

459.

Id.

460.

Id. at 668–69 (further noting that "eighty percent of marketed brand drugs never earn enough sales" to recoup development costs).

461.

Id. at 670.

462.

See id. at 670–71.

463.

Id. at 694.

464.

See, e.g., Erika Lietzan, A Solution in Search of a Problem at the Biologics Frontier, 2018 U. Ill. L. Rev. Online 19, 27 (2018).

465.

Id.

466.

Id. ("[G]eneric companies choose to rely on automatic substitution but could in fact market their products.").

467.

Id. ("[R]ational payers and physicians will select the generic first-generation product if the innovative second-generation product is not meaningfully better.").

468.

See, e.g., Schneiderman v. Actavis PLC, 787 F.3d 638 (2d Cir. 2015).

469.

Id. at 655 ("As long as Defendants sought to persuade patients and their doctors to switch from Namenda IR to Namenda XR while both were on the market (the soft switch) and with generic IR drugs on the horizon, patients and doctors could evaluate the products and their generics on the merits in furtherance of competitive objectives.").

470.

Id.

471.

Id at 654. ("Defendants' hard switch crosses the line from persuasion to coercion and is anticompetitive.").

472.

See id. at 658.

473.

Id.

474.

Id. at 662.

475.

Stu Woolman et al., Evidence of Patent Thickets in Complex Biopharmaceutical Technologies, 53 IDEA: Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 1, 2 (2013); Carl Shapiro, Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard-Setting, 1 Innovation Pol'y & Econ. 119, 119 (2001).

476.

See Gavin D. George, What Is Hiding in the Bushes? eBay's Effect on Holdout Behavior in Patent Thickets, 13 Mich. Telecomm. & Tech. L. Rev. 557, 558–60 (2007) (summarizing the economic literature); see generally Shapiro, supra note 475; Michael A. Heller & Rebecca Eisenberg, Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research, 280 Sci. 698, 698 (1998).

477.

Koons, supra note 372 (using "patent thicket" to refer to large patent portfolio amassed on one product by single biologics manufacturer); see also Feldman, supra note 372 ("[D]rug companies build massive patent walls around their products, extending the protection over and over again.").

478.

Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, Policy Levers in Patent Law, 89 Va. L. Rev. 1575, 1590–91 (2003) (stating that a one-to-one correspondence between patents and products "is the exception rather than the rule").

479.

Steve Lohr, Apple-Samsung Patent Battle Shifts to Trial, N.Y. Times, (July 29, 2012), https://www.nytimes.com/2012/07/30/technology/apple-samsung-trial-highlights-patent-wars.html. Notably, not all of the patents covering aspects of a smartphone are owned by the same entity. Id.

480.

Evan Engstrom, So How Many Patents Are In A Smartphone?, Engine (Jan. 19, 2017) https://www.engine.is/news/category/so-how-many-patents-are-in-a-smartphone.

481.

Burk & Lemley, supra note 478, at 159; see also Dmitry Karshtedt, The More Things Change: Improvement Patents, Drug Modifications, and the FDA, 104 Iowa L. Rev. 1129, 1158 (2019).

482.

Koons, supra note 372 ("[B]iologic medicines such as Humira . . . are typically made in living cells rather than chemically manufactured. That process often involves more steps and a higher level of complexity, which opens the door to more potential steps to patent.").

483.

See, e.g., Ass'n for Molecular Pathology v. Myriad Genetics, Inc., 569 U.S. 576, 590–94 (2013).

484.

See, e.g., Amgen, Inc. v. Coherus BioScis. Inc., 931 F.3d 1154, 1156 (Fed. Cir. 2019) (describing patent on purifying step of manufacturing a biologic).

485.

See Diamond v. Chakrabarty, 447 U.S. 303, 309–10 (1980) (upholding patent on genetically engineered bacterium).

486.

See Koons, supra note 372.

487.

Id. ("[C]ompanies can claim any changes to their drugs over the years—say, using a slightly different medium in which to grow cells or adjusting the dosing—warrant new legal protections that can keep generic competitors at bay.").

488.

Id.

489.

See AbbVie Inc. v. Boehringer Ingelheim Int'l GmbH, No. 17-CV-01065-MSG-RL, 2019 WL 917990, at *4 (D. Del. Feb. 25, 2019) (summarizing allegation that AbbVie created a "thicket of dubious and overlapping patents to delay biosimilar competition").

490.

Mayor and City Council of Baltimore v. AbbVie Inc., 42 F.4th 709, 710 (7th Cir. 2022).

491.

In re Humira (Adalimumab) Antitrust Litig., 465 F. Supp. 3d 811, 820 (N.D. Ill. 2020), aff'd, AbbVie, 42 F.4th at 716.

492.

Failure to Launch, supra note 373, at 8.

493.

Complaint at 1, AbbVie v. Boehringer Ingelheim Int'l GMBH, No. 1:17-cv-01065-MSG-RL (D. Del. Feb. 25, 2019) (stating that Humira "has resulted in more than 100 issued United States patents . . . 74 of which AbbVie has identified as infringed").

494.

Andrew Dunn, With Boehringer Settlement, AbbVie Completes Humira Sweep, BiopharmaDive (May 14, 2019), https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/abbvie-boehringer-ingelheim-settle-humira-patent-biosimilar/554729/.

495.

Id.

496.

Mayor and City Council of Baltimore v. AbbVie Inc., 42 F.4th 709, 714 (7th Cir. 2022). In Europe, by contrast, Humira biosimilars entered markets in Oct. 2018, and within four months captured 15% of the European market. Ned Pagliarulo, Humira Biosimilars Launch in Europe, Testing AbbVie, BiopharmaDive (Oct. 19, 2018), https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/abbvie-humira-biosimilars-launch-europe/539938/; Dunn, supra note 494 ("Humira biosimilars captured 15% of the European market in February, the fourth month since launching."). It is estimated that biosimilars could claim up to 50% of the Humira market in Europe within the first year. Id. ("[B]iosimilars growing to take 50% of the Humira market in Europe within a year remains a possibility.").

497.

See In re Humira (Adalimumab) Antitrust Litig., 465 F. Supp. 3d 811, 82-26 (N.D. Ill. 2020), aff'd, AbbVie, 42 F.4th at 716. The complaint also presents "state law claims for conspiracy and combination in restraint of trade, monopolization, state consumer protection law violation, and unjust enrichment." See Complaint, In re Humira (Adalimumab) Antitrust Litig., 465 F. Supp. 3d 811 (N.D. Ill. 2020) (No. 19 CV 1873).

498.

In re Humira (Adalimumab) Antitrust Litig., 465 F. Supp. 3d 811, 819 (N.D. Ill. 2020), aff'd, AbbVie, 42 F.4th at 716.

499.

AbbVie, 42 F.4th at 712–13.

500.

Id.

501.

See supra "Evergreening"

502.

Ned Pagliarulo, Coherus Wins Humira Patent Ruling, Chipping Away at AbbVies' Defenses, BiopharmaDive (May 17, 2017), https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/coherus-humira-patent-abbvie-ipr-biosimilar/442950/.

503.

See Andrei Iancu, Humira Shows That America's Patent Innovation System Is Working, Bloomberg Law (Feb. 24, 2023), https://news.bloomberglaw.com/us-law-week/humira-shows-that-americas-patent-innovation-system-is-working ("The more inventive a company is, the more patents it usually gets.").

504.

Sy Mukherjee, Protect at All Costs: How the Maker of the World's Bestselling Drug Keeps Prices Sky-High, Fortune (July 18, 2019), https://fortune.com/longform/abbvie-humira-drug-costs-innovation/.

505.

See Koons, supra note 372; Iancu, supra note 503.

506.

Mukherjee, supra note 504.

507.

Id.

508.

See id.

509.

Id.

510.

Mayor and City Council of Baltimore v. AbbVie Inc., 42 F.4th 709, 712–14 (7th Cir. 2022).

511.

See supra "Evergreening"

512.

See, e.g., Gilead Sci., Inc. v. Natco Pharma Ltd., 753 F.3d 1208, 1210 (Fed. Cir. 2014); STC.UNM v. Intel Corp., 754 F.3d 940, 942 (Fed. Cir. 2014).

513.

See supra "Patent Dispute Procedures for Generic Drugs and Biosimilars."

514.

See, e.g., FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136, 144–45 (2013); In re Androgel Antitrust Litig., No. 1:09-MD-2084-TWT, 2018 WL 298483, at *3–4 (N.D. Ga. June 14, 2018).

515.

Id.

516.

See, e.g., Actavis, 570 U.S. at 154.

517.

In re Lipitor Antitrust Litig., 868 F.3d 231 (3d Cir. 2017).

518.

Id. at 239.

519.

Id. at 247 ("On December 10, 2002, Teva obtained ANDA first-filer status for a generic version of Effexor XR. Teva's ANDA included paragraph IV certifications, asserting that Teva's sale, marketing, or use of generic Effexor would not infringe Wyeth's patents or that those patents were invalid or unenforceable. . . . Within the 45-day period prescribed by the Hatch-Waxman Act, Wyeth brought suit against Teva for patent infringement in the District of New Jersey.").

520.

Id.

521.

An "authorized generic" is the same as the brand name drug, but marketed without the brand name on its label. An authorized generic may be marketed by the brand name drug company, or another company with the brand company's permission. See FDA, List of Authorized Generic Drugs, https://www.fda.gov/drugs/abbreviated-new-drug-application-anda/fda-list-authorized-generic-drugs (last visited Jan. 8, 2024). Some commentators have noted that brand companies may use the launch of an authorized generic in order to earn additional revenue from generic market entry and reduce the amount an ANDA challenger may earn from sales of its generic during its 180-day period of exclusivity. See Gregory Glass, Authorized Generics, 4 Nature Reviews Drug Discovery 953, 953 (2005).

522.

See In re Lipitor, 868 F.3d at 247.

523.

Id. Pursuant to a 2002 consent decree, the FTC "possessed the right to weigh in on and raise objections to Wyeth's settlements." Id.

524.

Id. While "[t]he FTC offered no objection" to the settlement agreement, it "reserved its right to take later action." Id.

525.

FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136, 147–48 (2013); see also King Drug Co. of Florence, Inc. v. Smithkline Beecham Corp., 791 F.3d 388, 398 (3d Cir. 2015).

526.

NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 103 (1984) (quoting Nat'l Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 690 (1978)).

527.

Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. at 141.

528.

See, e.g., Smithkline Beecham Corp., 791 F.3d at 403; King Drug Co. of Florence, Inc. v. Cephalon, Inc., 88 F. Supp. 3d 402, 422 (E.D. Pa. 2015); In re Aggrenox Antitrust Litig., 94 F. Supp. 3d 224, 245–46 (D. Conn. 2015).

529.

Dunn, supra note 494.

530.

Failure to Launch, supra note 373, at 8 ("[A] critical element of biosimilar entry is the ability for two parties to reach a settlement agreement providing for competition earlier than the expiration of the last patent, rather than bear the time and expense of litigating through these thickets in court.").

531.

Id. (stating that fewer agreements of the kind at issue in Actavis "paved the way for pro-consumer patent settlement agreements and earlier entry while avoiding expensive and burdensome litigation costs").

532.

Actavis, 570 U.S. at 158–60.

533.

Fed. Trade Comm'n, Bureau of Competition, Agreements Filed With the Federal Trade Commission Under the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003: Overview of Agreements Filed In Fiscal Year 2017: A Report By the Bureau of Competition (Dec. 4, 2020), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/agreements-filed-federal-trade-commission-under-medicare-prescription-drug-improvement-modernization/mma_report_fy2017.pdf.

534.

Id.

535.

Id. at 159.

536.

Id. at 156.

537.

Id.; see also id. at 159.

538.

Id. at 159; see also United States v. Brown Univ., 5 F.3d 658, 668 (3d Cir. 1993) ("The plaintiff bears an initial burden under the rule of reason of showing that the alleged combination or agreement produced adverse, anti-competitive effects within the relevant product and geographic markets.").

539.

In re Lipitor Antitrust Litig., 868 F.3d 231, 248 (3d Cir. 2017).

540.

Id. at 258–62.

541.

Id. at 260 ("The no-[authorized-generic (AG)] agreement used by Wyeth to induce Teva to stay out of the Effexor XR market was alleged to have been worth more than $500 million.").

542.

Id. at 261.

543.

Id. at 262 (stating that the plaintiffs' complaints "contain sufficient factual detail about the settlement agreement between Teva and Wyeth to plausibly suggest that Wyeth paid Teva to stay out of the market by way of its no-AG agreement [and] that is the very anticompetitive harm that the Supreme Court identified in Actavis").

544.

Carrier & Shadowen, supra note 370, at 176–77 ("Put simply, the brand firm will be much more successful in forestalling generic competition if it can switch the market to the reformulated drug before a generic of the original product enters the market.").

545.

Id. at 177 ("In the TriCor case, . . . the brand firm predicted that it would sell more than ten times as many tablets if it was able to switch doctors to the reformulated product before the generic version of the original product entered the market.").

546.

Carrier, supra note 374, at 1022–27.

547.

Id. at 1022.

548.

Id. at 1022–23 ("The four first-filing generic firms planned for a launch in June 2006, at the latest.").

549.

Id. at 1023 ("A Cephalon vice president projected a 75%–90% price reduction that would lower revenues by more than $400 million (nearly 75% of the drug's annual sales) within one year.").

550.

Id. at 1023–25.

551.

Id. at 1024 ("Cephalon paid more than $200 million to the four generic firms to agree to forgo entry until April 2012.").

552.

Id. at 1025 ("The easiest way to make Provigil less desirable was to increase its price. . . . Another means to reduce Provigil's attractiveness was to stop promoting it.").

553.

Id. at 1026.